Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

October 11, 2011

Did the Fed’s Term Auction Facility Work?

James J. McAndrews, Asani Sarkar, and Zhenyu Wang

The Federal Reserve introduced the Term Auction Facility (TAF) in December 2007 to provide term loans to banks during the recent financial crisis. In this post, we report on the effectiveness of the TAF during the early stages of the crisis. We find that the TAF was associated with a decrease in the “liquidity premium,” one component of a bank’s borrowing cost. In other words, the TAF worked as intended.


    During fall 2007, the spread between the London interbank offered rate (Libor) and the overnight indexed swap (OIS) for loans of one-month maturity or longer rose to unusually high levels (see chart below). It is widely believed that the increase in the Libor–OIS spread reflected the heightened risk perceived by investors at the time, in part due to the increased uncertainty of access to the short-term loan markets. Since Libor affects interest rates on a wide variety of loans and securities (for example, home mortgages and corporate loans), the sudden spike in the spread was disruptive to the debt market and negatively affected the economy. The chart and the accompanying table also show six announcements related to the TAF program. The announcements indicate increases in TAF funding, with the exception of announcement 4 (in green), which indicates a decrease in the availability of TAF funds in February 2008.

Libor-OIS-spread

    The TAF facility provided term funding through periodic auctions to eligible depository institutions that were in sound financial condition. The total amount of funds available at any TAF auction was announced in advance by the Fed, and the rate (known as the “stop-out rate”) was set in a competitive auction among the participating depository institutions. Those depositories with the highest bid rates received funds at the stop-out rate. Through auctions, the Fed provided term funds to depositories that needed it most, with the intention of alleviating strains that had arisen from the unwillingness of sound institutions to lend to one another or to borrow from the discount window individually. Armantier, Krieger, and McAndrews discuss the design of the TAF in detail.

    From December 17, 2007, to April 21, 2008, the Federal Reserve completed ten TAF auctions providing mostly twenty-eight-day term loans. There was substantial demand for funds at the auctions during that period. The number of banks bidding for the term loans in the TAF varied between fifty-two and ninety-three, and the bid/cover ratio (that is, the total amount of funds bid as a ratio of funds auctioned) ranged from 1.25 to 3.08. The amount of term loans auctioned was $20 billion in each of the first two auctions, $30 billion in the next four auctions, and $50 billion in the last four auctions. The chart below shows a steady increase in the amount of TAF loans outstanding (reflecting new loans less old loans repaid by banks) as the money markets became increasingly stressed.

TAF-loans-outstanding

    Why did the Fed think the TAF could be helpful in reducing the liquidity risk premium (represented by the Libor–OIS spread) in the term interest rate? One reason could be that banks with surplus funds were hoarding them rather than lending them out to other banks—because they were uncertain about their own sources of future funding, they expected greater funding needs themselves, or both. By providing term funds to banks at regularly scheduled auctions, the TAF may have assured lenders of continued access to future funding and thereby reduced their uncertainty regarding anticipated funding needs.

    The Libor–OIS spread fell in December 2007 when the TAF program was announced, but then began to increase again in January 2008. Did the TAF program succeed in abating this increase in the Libor–OIS spread? Our analysis shows that the Libor–OIS spread decreased on TAF event days (defined either as days when there was an announcement about the program, or days when there was a TAF auction or some other operation). We find that the average decrease in the Libor–OIS spread was about 2 basis points per TAF event.

Lib-OIS-decreas-event-days

    While the Fed initially committed to only four TAF auctions, it subsequently announced that TAF funding would be provided “as long as necessary.” (The TAF program ended in March 2010.)  Announcements of the continuation and expansion of the TAF program may have been just as important in reassuring fearful lenders in the money markets as were the actual auctions themselves. In fact, when we break out the effects of TAF announcements and operations on the Libor–OIS spread (see chart below), we see that the announcement effects were indeed substantial. Therefore, exclusion of the announcement effects would result in a severe underestimation of the benefits of the TAF program, perhaps leading to the erroneous conclusion that it did not bring down interest rates.

Libor-OIS-spread-decreased

    The TAF was just one of many facilities designed by the Fed during the crisis to improve liquidity conditions in various asset
markets. By focusing on the early period of the crisis (before May 2008), we are better able to isolate the effects of TAF from other funding facilities that were introduced in the later stages of the crisis. Identifying the impact of a liquidity facility such as the TAF was crucial for the design of other funding facilities during the crisis. Data indicate that the TAF complemented the Fed’s efforts to support and improve the liquidity in short-term funding markets.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author(s).

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives