Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

February 29, 2016

The “Cadillac Tax”: Driving Firms to Change Their Plans?

LSE_2016_cadillac-tax_dussault_460_art

Since the 1940s, employers that provide health insurance for their employees can deduct the cost as a business expense, but the government does not treat the value of that coverage as taxable income. This exclusion of employer-provided health insurance from taxable income—$248 billion in 2013, according to the Congressional Budget Office—is a huge subsidy for health spending. Many economists cite the distortionary effects of this tax subsidy as an important reason for why U.S. health care spending accounts for such a large share of the economy and why spending historically has grown so rapidly. In this blog post, we focus on a provision of the Affordable Care Act (ACA) that is intended to chip away at this tax subsidy, the colloquially labelled “Cadillac Tax” on the priciest employer-provided health insurance plans.


Drawing on results from business surveys conducted in August 2015 by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, as well as the more comprehensive 2015 Employer Health Benefits Survey published by the Kaiser Family Foundation, we explore the possible impact of this provision on businesses in the Second District and how individual firms might respond.

About the Excise Tax

The Cadillac Tax is a 40 percent excise tax on the amount by which a health plan’s total cost of coverage exceeds a legislated threshold ($10,200 for individual coverage or $27,500 for family coverage). For firms that do not self-insure, a health plan’s cost is determined by its annual premiums (including the shares paid by both the employer and employee), Flexible Spending Account contributions, and other health reimbursement contributions. In these cases, the insurance company is responsible for paying the tax. For employers offering self-insured plans, the values of these plans are determined using IRS protocols and the employer is responsible for paying the tax. In both cases, the cost of the tax will likely be shared between employers and employees. Although most of the major provisions of the ACA have already kicked in, the Cadillac Tax is the only major one yet to take effect. Its scheduled implementation was recently pushed back by Congress from 2018 to 2020.

Since the Cadillac Tax could potentially apply to a wide variety of firms, its impact on managerial decisions is of interest. In our August 2015 Empire State Manufacturing Survey and Business Leaders Survey, the respondents were asked to complete a supplemental section on the ACA and their health coverage more broadly. In particular, firms were asked if the “Cadillac Tax” (then projected to take effect in 2018) would apply to their health plans as they stood at that time.

Out of the 225 manufacturing and service sector firms that answered this question, 19 percent said their plans would be subject to the tax, 45 percent said their plans would not be subject, and 36 percent were unsure. Why, one might ask, would so many firms be unsure about their plan’s status? Some might have never heard of the Cadillac Tax, some might be unsure of the tax’s thresholds or fine print, and some might not know their plan’s exact costs. Therefore, we decided to compare only firms that said yes, their plans would be subject to the tax (referred to below as Cadillac-yes firms), to firms that said no (referred to as Cadillac-no firms).

Who Will Be Affected?

The Cadillac Tax is likely to have a differential impact on firms. For instance, large firms tend to be better able to afford high cost plans than small firms, and therefore are more likely to have plans that will be subject to the tax. The 2015 Kaiser Family Foundation survey found that large firms—those with 200 or more workers—were both more likely to investigate the possibility that their plan would fall under the specifications of the Cadillac Tax, and to report that their highest cost plan would exceed the threshold.

Similarly, larger firms in our August 2015 surveys were also more likely to indicate that they would be subject to the Cadillac Tax than were smaller firms. Out of firms with 200 or more full-time workers in 2015, 28 percent said their plans would be subject to the tax, compared with only 15 percent of firms with fewer than 200 full-time workers. Cadillac-yes firms were also more likely to characterize themselves as large corporations than Cadillac-no firms. Additionally, Cadillac-no firms were more likely to classify themselves as primarily self-contained at one location. Since firms that will be subject to the Cadillac Tax tend to be large, a high share of employees could potentially be affected.

Certain industries also tend to offer more generous health benefits. Firms in these industries might therefore be more likely to offer plans that would be subject to the Cadillac Tax. For instance, we found that Cadillac-yes firms were more likely to be classified as “Health, Education, and Social Assistance” firms than Cadillac-no firms.

How Are Firms Responding?

How are those businesses that project being affected by the Cadillac Tax responding to the proposed tax? Since the marginal federal income tax rate of most employers is less than 40 percent, the Cadillac Tax actually increases a firm’s tax liability more than if it were simply no longer allowed to deduct that portion of health plan benefits above the threshold. Thus, for employers with health insurance plans that are expected to exceed the thresholds, this tax should provide a strong incentive to switch to less expensive plans or to shrink their plan’s benefits.

In the Kaiser Family Foundation survey, 8 percent of all firms offering health benefits reported switching to a lower cost plan in anticipation of the tax. The plan changes they made included increasing cost sharing, reducing the scope of covered services, and increasing incentives to use less costly providers.

Similar trends emerged in our August 2015 surveys. Among the firms responding to our surveys, 64 percent of Cadillac-yes firms said that they are making modifications to their health plan or switching to a new provider in response to the ACA in general. This compares to 55 percent of Cadillac-no firms. Among firms making changes, some responses from Cadillac-yes and Cadillac-no firms are similar: The vast majority of these firms are retrenching their plans by raising total premiums, deductibles, and out-of-pocket maximums.

What is more interesting in our surveys is that Cadillac-yes respondents are more inclined than Cadillac-no respondents to be decreasing the number of plan options and decreasing the range of services covered. Among firms making changes, 30 percent of Cadillac-yes firms are decreasing the number of plan options they offer, compared to 16 percent of Cadillac-no firms. Since the excise tax will only apply if an employee chooses a high-cost plan, firms may be dropping their highest cost plans in order to avoid that risk. In addition, Cadillac-yes firms are much more likely than Cadillac-no firms to be reducing the range of services covered—a strategy that firms with high health care costs could be using to reduce these costs and therefore stay below the Cadillac threshold. This retrenchment behavior is consistent with firms making incremental changes to their plans now in anticipation of the tax, since changes take time to implement. Surprisingly, Cadillac-yes firms are no more likely than Cadillac-no firms to reduce the size of their networks. This would seem like a technique firms could use to avoid the excise tax.

Potential Impact of the Cadillac Tax

Although one of the goals of the Cadillac Tax is to raise revenue in order to help pay for other provisions of the ACA, another—perhaps more important—goal is to provide incentives for employers to shop for less expensive health insurance, and thus decrease health spending. So if firms change their behavior to try to avoid the Cadillac Tax, this will not be an unintended consequence, but rather part of the role of the tax as envisioned by the ACA. In this way, the Cadillac Tax differs from most other taxes. If businesses that believe themselves likely to be subject to the Cadillac Tax respond by switching to less expensive health insurance plans, the Cadillac Tax will have done its job in the eyes of its architects.

Ultimately, since firms are making decisions in response to a wide array of ACA provisions, it is hard to isolate their decisions in response to the Cadillac Tax from their decisions in response to other ACA features. We did not ask firms what changes they are making specifically because of the Cadillac Tax, so we can only comment on how the responses to general ACA questions differed between Cadillac-yes firms and Cadillac-no firms. Furthermore, because our sample only includes 225 firms, and since the survey questions were more impressionistic than quantitative, we are reluctant to view the responses with too much precision or to draw conclusions about causality. So we would like to pose a few questions to our business-leader readers: What changes have you made to your firm’s health plan or to your business as a direct response to the prospect of the Cadillac Tax? Is the Cadillac Tax a provision of the ACA that your firm is concerned about?

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.


Bram_jason
Jason Bram is a research officer in the Research and Statistics Group.

Dussault_nicoleNicole Dussault is a senior research analyst in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

Pinkovskiy_maxim
Maxim L.Pinkovskiy is an economist in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives