Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

February 24, 2014

What Makes a Bank Stable? A Framework for Analysis

Thomas M. Eisenbach and Tanju Yorulmazer

One of the major roles of banks and other financial intermediaries is to channel funds from savings into valuable projects. In doing so, banks engage in “liquidity and maturity transformation,” since they finance long-term, illiquid projects while funding themselves with short-term, liquid liabilities. By performing this important role, banks expose themselves to the risk of runs: If depositors or other short-term creditors worry about their claims, they may withdraw funds en masse and cause the bank to fail. The recent financial crisis once again highlighted the fragility associated with financial intermediaries performing the roles of maturity and liquidity transformation. This post draws upon our paper “Stability of Funding Models: An Analytical Framework” to illustrate the determinants of a financial intermediary’s ability to survive stress events.


We use a simple framework, where the bank has the following balance sheet: Chart_1
        On the asset side of the balance sheet, the bank has cash and risky assets, for example, loans to companies. The main feature of cash is that it’s safe – one dollar is always worth one dollar. The risky assets are different in two important ways: First, their value is uncertain (some borrowers may default on their loans); second, the risky assets are long-term investments. If the bank has to raise money quickly, it has to sell its loans. Potential buyers, such as other banks, may not know the companies as well and therefore may not be willing to pay face value for the loan. Hence, asset sales entail liquidation costs. On the liability side, the financial intermediary has equity that acts as a buffer against losses, long-term debt that has the same maturity as the risky assets, and short-term debt that can be rolled over or redeemed earlier.

        When some short-term creditors don’t roll over their claims, the financial intermediary pays them using cash first; if cash isn’t enough, the intermediary starts to liquidate some of the risky assets, which is costly. In our framework, the intermediary can fail for two main reasons:

  • Low asset returns: Fundamental insolvency due to erosion of equity by low asset returns that don’t cover the bank’s debt burden.
  • Loss of funding: Costly liquidation of assets and “fire sales” that erode equity.

        The diagram below illustrates our framework. On the y-axis, we have the return from the risky assets. On the x-axis, we have the loss of short-term funding, for example, the proportion of short-term creditors who don’t roll over their claims.

Chart2

        The diagram has four main regions for different combinations of asset return and loss of funding. At one extreme, when the asset return is very high (the area above the dashed line), the bank can stay solvent, even if it loses all short-term funding and needs to liquidate some of the risky assets at a cost. At the other extreme, when the asset return is very low (the blue area), even if all short-term creditors roll over their debt, the bank can’t cover its debt burden and is “fundamentally insolvent.”

        Interesting cases arise for intermediate values of the asset return, where the intermediary’s ability to stay solvent depends on how much short-term funding it loses. For an intermediate asset return, if few creditors refuse to roll over their claims, the bank doesn’t have to sell too many assets and can stay solvent. If, however, for the same asset return, too many creditors refuse to roll over their claims, the bank suffers significant liquidation costs and becomes insolvent. In the diagram, the red line represents the solvency threshold. Below and to the right of the red line, due to low asset returns or significant loss of short-term funding, the bank has negative equity and becomes insolvent (the shaded triangle). Banks in this situation are also referred to as “solvent but illiquid,” since they could have stayed solvent in principle, but due to the illiquidity of their assets the loss of short-term funding forces them into insolvency.

        The diagram provides a simple yet powerful framework for analyzing the inherent fragility of financial intermediaries and for uncovering the different causes of a financial intermediary’s failure. In a forthcoming post, we’ll use our framework to analyze how various policy and balance sheet changes affect the financial fragility of financial intermediaries.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.


Eisenbach_thomas Thomas M. Eisenbach is an economist in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Yorulmazer_tanju
Tanju Yorulmazer research officer in the Group.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives