Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

August 11, 2014

Inflation in the Great Recession and New Keynesian Models

Since the financial crisis of 2007-08 and the Great Recession, many commentators have been baffled by the “missing deflation” in the face of a large and persistent amount of slack in the economy. Some prominent academics have argued that existing models cannot properly account for the evolution of inflation during and following the crisis. For example, in his American Economic Association presidential address, Robert E. Hall called for a fundamental reconsideration of Phillips curve models and their modern incarnation—so-called dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models—in which inflation depends on a measure of slack in economic activity. The argument is that such theories should have predicted more and more disinflation as long as the unemployment rate remained above a natural rate of, say, 6 percent. Since inflation declined somewhat in 2009, and then remained positive, Hall concludes that such theories based on a concept of slack must be wrong.

In an NBER working paper and a New York Fed staff report (forthcoming in the American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics), we use a standard New Keynesian DSGE model with financial frictions to explain the behavior of output and inflation since the crisis. This model was estimated using data up to 2008. We find that following the increase in financial stress in 2008, the model successfully predicts not only the sharp contraction in economic activity, but also only a modest decline in inflation.

The left panel of the next chart shows the output growth forecasts made with information right after the collapse of Lehman Brothers, which sparked the recent financial crisis. The black solid lines show the available data at that time, the red solid line is the model’s forecast, and the black dashed lines correspond to realized data. When made aware of the financial consequences of the Lehman default with corporate bond spread data, the DSGE model predicts a sharp drop in GDP and a very sluggish recovery. Indeed, the model’s forecast for output in 2012:Q3 (right panel) is remarkably close to the actual value. Quite strikingly, based on the information available post Lehman, the DSGE model predicts output to be well below the pre-2008 trend four years after the financial crisis.

Chart l shows Forecasts of Output Growth and Output Level

In the next chart at left, we depict the DSGE model-implied output gap. Loosely speaking, this is the difference between output and potential output, defined as the counterfactual level of output in an economy without nominal rigidities and financial frictions. The illustration makes the point that the low level of output after 2008:Q4 is not an efficient outcome for the economy, according to the model (or, in other words, is not due to a fall in potential output). In 2008:Q4, the model forecasts large and persistent gaps (up to -7 percent), which are only slightly smaller by the end of the sample (about -6 percent). The estimated output gap is somewhat larger in absolute terms than the forecasted one, nearing -10 percent by the end of 2009, and it recovers only gradually.

The right panel shows the inflation forecasts, with inflation measured by the GDP deflator. The DSGE model misses the brief deflation in 2009:Q1, which was due to falling energy prices, and the rise in inflation in 2010 and the beginning of 2011 coinciding with the surge in commodity prices. But aside from these transitory movements, the model produces reasonable inflation forecasts. To sum up, using information available at the end of 2008, the DSGE model predicts a drop in output growth of roughly the same magnitude as the actual one as well as the subsequent sluggish recovery with a large and persistent output gap. However, unlike Hall’s conjecture, the model does not predict deflation.

Chart 2 shows Forecasts of the Output Gap and Inflation

Why does the model not forecast persistent deflation? We will return to this question in more detail in Wednesday’s post. For now, we note that in this New Keynesian model inflation is determined by firms’ expectations of future marginal costs. (Marginal costs—the costs of producing additional units of output—are not directly observed, but are inferred by the model.) We therefore inspect the marginal cost forecasts shown in the solid red line in the left panel of the next chart. The picture makes clear that even when firms saw their actual costs fall in the midst of the downturn, they were expecting their marginal costs to return eventually to normal levels.

One might think that there would have been more disinflation if firms had known ahead of time how low their marginal cost would turn out to be (shown by the dashed line). To dispel that idea, we reproduce in the right panel the model’s baseline forecast of inflation (solid red line) from the previous chart and depict an alternative inflation forecast (dashed red line) that is obtained assuming that the actual path of marginal costs is known at the time of the forecasts. The resulting forecast for inflation is, of course, lower than the baseline forecast, but not dramatically so.

Chart 3 shows Forecasts of Marginal Costs and Inflation

The forward-looking nature of the model’s Phillips curve is crucial to understanding the lack of disinflation in the face of substantial economic slack. Indeed, a backward-looking Phillips curve, according to which inflation depends on the realized unemployment rate and past inflation rates (dashed blue line), forecasts a deflation of about 2 percent annualized. To rationalize the positive inflation we have seen in recent years, proponents of backward-looking Phillips curves have resorted to other measures that show the economy faced relatively little slack, despite the magnitude of the Great Recession. (This is in part why there has been so much focus recently on short-term unemployment, which has returned to pre-recession levels, rather than total unemployment as a measure of slack. See, for example, Krueger, Cramer, and Cho 2014).

In modern New Keynesian DSGE models, however, the present value of expected future marginal costs is the more meaningful way of measuring slack. This implies that inflation may remain stable in the face of a large drop in current marginal costs, provided that marginal costs are expected to rise sufficiently in the future. In our model, monetary policy accommodation is the key reason why marginal costs are projected to rebound, as we will explain in more detail in our next post.

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.


Del_negro_marco

Marco Del Negro is an assistant vice president in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Giannoni_marc

Marc Giannoni is an assistant vice president in the Research and Statistics Group.

At the time this post was written, Raiden Hasegawa was a senior research analyst in the Research and Statistics Group.

Frank Schorfheide is a professor of economics at University of Pennsylvania.

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

Houses can be bought for 10 to 20 cents on the dollar. The deflation was mostly in Real Estate.

The comments to this entry are closed.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives