Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

September 12, 2016

Is There Discount Window Stigma in the United Kingdom?

LSE_Is There Discount Window Stigma in the United Kingdom?

At the onset of the financial crisis in the summer of 2007, news that Barclays had borrowed from the Bank of England (BoE) received wide media coverage. This information triggered concerns that the BoE’s lending facility may have become stigmatized, prompting market participants to interpret borrowing from the BoE as a sign of financial weakness. If such stigma discouraged borrowing, of course, it would defeat the purpose of the facility. We review the history of the BoE’s lending facilities and experiences with stigma, both historically and in the recent period. We also compare the BoE’s and the Fed’s lending facilities, and conclude that bilateral lending by central banks may tend to become stigmatized to some extent, no matter how the lending facility is structured.

Central Bank Lending to Financial Institutions in the U.K. and the U.S.

In this post, we contrast “bilateral lending” (in other words, lending to a particular financial institution) with lending simultaneously to potentially multiple institutions via an auction. We then define “discount window (DW) lending” broadly, to mean any bilateral lending by a central bank to a financial institution, irrespective of the particular funding need. Historically, the Fed has always used one bilateral lending facility for both routine and emergency purposes, while the BoE has, over the years, introduced different bilateral lending facilities to separate routine lending from lending for more severe liquidity shortages.

Before the Barclays episode, we do not find any reference to stigma associated with the BoE’s bilateral lending facilities in either the media or in academic literature. By contrast, concerns regarding DW stigma at the Fed date back to the 1920s. Three aspects of the BoE’s policies may have contributed to the apparent lack of concern about stigma, at least during the early history of the BoE, as we further discuss below. As compared to the Fed, the BoE better integrated bilateral lending activities into its monetary policy implementation framework; did not always separately disclose bilateral lending activities; and adhered more closely to classical lender-of-last-resort principles but without attaching onerous restrictions that might send mixed signals about the appropriateness of borrowing from the central bank.

The Role of Lending in the BoE’s Monetary Policy until 2006

Until 2006, when the BoE reformed its monetary policy framework, the central bank conducted bilateral lending toward the end of the day as an integral part of its routine monetary policy operations. From the mid-1800s to the 1970s, bilateral DW lending was the BoE’s primary tool for temporarily increasing liquidity in the banking system (see the chart below), while outright purchases or sales of securities were used for more permanent changes. In the 1980s, the BoE began to use repos in the open market for temporary increases in liquidity, but continued to conduct routine bilateral lending for institutions with liquidity needs arising from late-day imbalances. Thus, until 2006, the BoE’s policy fundamentally differed from the Fed’s, which ceased conducting bilateral lending as part of its routine monetary policy operations starting in the late 1920s. Continued inclusion of bilateral lending in the BoE’s monetary policy operations prevented the lending from being associated with unusual circumstances.

LSE_Evolution of Lending

Disclosure of Lending Data until 2006

The BoE and the Fed also differed in their disclosure practices before 2006. Since the Bank Charter Act of 1844, the BoE was required to publish a weekly summary of its key assets and liabilities, known as the Bank Return. The Bank Return was similar to the Fed’s weekly release titled “Factors Affecting Reserve Balances of Depository Institutions and Condition Statement of Federal Reserve Banks,” and included a line item on the level of loans outstanding each week. Before the 1980s, DW lending accounted for all of the outstanding loans shown in the Bank Return. However, starting in the 1980s, as the BoE lent increasingly through repos in the open market, the line item also began to include these operations without separating the various types of lending activities (see the chart below). The Fed, by contrast, has always separated the various lending activities in its weekly release. The upshot is that for close to thirty years, the BoE in effect did not separately disclose lending information by type, limiting the potential for individual borrowers to be identified and potentially stigmatized.

LSE_Disclosure of Lending

BoE’s Lending Facilities since 2006

In 2006, the BoE replaced the end-of-day bilateral lending operations with a standing bilateral lending facility, for use at any time of the day, akin to the standing facility at the Fed. Lending under the new standing facility became less routine and more separated from open market operations. Since the new facility was rarely if ever used, any borrowing drew attention. At the same time, the BoE also started disclosing standing facility loans separately from open market repos in the Bank Return (see the chart below), drawing further attention to such borrowings. Even though the Bank Return does not actually name borrowers, market participants can sometimes deduce them.

LSE_Lending Facilities

In August 2007, Barclays’ sudden borrowings under the standing facility received wide media coverage. Although Barclays borrowed due to a technical breakdown of the U.K. clearing system and was not in financial trouble, other banks reportedly became reluctant to use the facility to avoid possible stigma.

To mitigate the stigma of borrowing from the standing facility, the BoE in 2008 renamed the facility as the Operational Standing Lending Facility (OSLF) to clarify its purpose as a facility for routine frictional payment shocks. A separate DW Facility (DWF) was introduced for lending for more severe liquidity shocks, and it typically lent gilts against a wider set of collateral.

The BoE also changed its disclosure policies. The requirement to publish the Bank Return—in place for 165 years—was lifted by the 2009 Banking Act. Although no longer legally required, the BoE has continued to publish the Bank Return (renamed the Weekly Report) but without disclosing bilateral lending information. Aggregate data on its bilateral lending activities are now disclosed with longer lags, thus limiting the potential for stigma.

Punitive Lending Rates

Finally, the BoE has consistently—before and after 2006—charged a punitive or “penal” rate on late day and other bilateral loans. This approach obviated the need for moral suasion or administrative restrictions to limit borrowing. Prior to the 1980s, the BOE’s policy rate represented the DW lending rate and was usually 50 basis points higher than the prevailing market rate. Since the 1980s, the BoE maintained a separate rate for late-day-bilateral loans that was as much as 100 basis points above the policy rate (see the chart below). In contrast, the rate on Fed DW loans was consistently below market rates until 2002. To prevent excessive or opportunistic borrowing, the Fed had to ration through highly intrusive, administrative restrictions, which sent mixed signals about the appropriateness of borrowing from the facilities.

LSE_Bank of England's Lending Rate vs Market Rates

DW Stigma Today

Concerns about stigma associated with the BoE’s standing lending facility came to the forefront during the financial crisis of 2007. In the 2012 Winters Report, which reviewed the BoE’s framework for providing liquidity to the banking system, it was noted that since the standing facility was recast in 2008, it was, for the most part, working as intended though there continue to be lingering concerns among a few banks. The report further indicated that borrowing at the BoE’s other DW facility, which was intended for more severe liquidity shocks, has become stigmatized. Similarly, anecdotal evidence suggests that the Fed’s DW facility also remains stigmatized.

Both at the BoE and the Fed, the rise of open market operations as the main tool of monetary policy has coincided with a reduced reliance on bilateral lending activities. Less frequent, less routine bilateral lending has, in turn, coincided with the rise of stigma concerns. In other words, stigma with bilateral lending may be due in part to its diminishing role in monetary policy. It may be that the solution hinges on reforming loan provision and disclosure practices to make it more difficult for individual borrowings to be identified and thereby stigmatized. In this context, it is interesting to note that the Fed’s Term Auction Facility, introduced after the crisis in December 2007, provided loans via an auction rather than bilaterally and appears to have substantially reduced or eliminated stigma. An auction-based facility may potentially better mitigate the stigma of borrowing from a central bank, provided there is active participation in the auctions.

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.



Helene_lee
Helene Lee is a senior associate in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Markets Group.

Sarkar_asani
Asani Sarkar is an assistant vice president in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Integrated Policy Analysis Group.

How to cite this blog post:
Helene Lee and Asani Sarkar, “Discount Window Stigma in the United Kingdom,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics (blog), September 12, 2016, http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2016/09/is-there-discount-window-stigma-in-the-uk.html.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives