Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

July 6, 2011

Discretionary Services Expenditures in This Business Cycle

Jonathan McCarthy

The pronounced weakness in personal consumption expenditures (PCE) for services has been an unusual feature of the 2007-09 recession and the slow recovery from it. Even in 2010:Q4, when real PCE increased at a relatively robust 4.1 percent annual rate, real PCE on services rose at only a 1.4 percent rate. This weakness has been especially evident in “discretionary” services (to be defined below), which fell more in the recent recession than in previous recessions and since have rebounded more sluggishly. In this post, I suggest that the continued sluggishness in these expenditures lends a note of caution regarding the sustainability of recent PCE strength. Because consumption accounts for about 70 percent of output, this in turn raises some concern about the future strength of the recovery.


Decomposition of Services

In this post, nondiscretionary services expenditures are defined in three broad categories: housing (tenant rent and owners’ equivalent rent), financial services without payment (as these are implicit expenditures), and health care. The remainder of services is considered to be discretionary, and includes categories such as recreation, transportation, food services (including restaurants), and household utilities. Even though all three nondiscretionary categories are large (totaling about 34 percent of total PCE), nearly 47 percent of services expenditures (and about 30 percent of total PCE) are categorized as discretionary in this decomposition.

How Severe Was the Fall in Discretionary Services?

The chart below shows how much real per capita (to account for differing rates of population growth over time) discretionary services expenditures fell from their previous peak—a zero value in this chart means that these expenditures were above their previous peak. The drop in discretionary services expenditures in the last recession was much more severe than in previous recessions: the nearly 7 percent fall from the peak is more than double the percentage decline in the early 1980s recession (the previous “champion” in this dimension).

Cummulative-declines

Furthermore, this outsized fall in discretionary services was an important contributor to the decline in real GDP during the recession. Suppose discretionary services expenditures had fallen about 2 percent in the recession, comparable to the declines in the previous two recessions. With no differences in other GDP components, the peak-to-trough decline in real GDP per capita then would have been about one percentage point less than the actual decrease, which is the difference between a GDP fall similar to previous severe postwar recessions (the 1973-75 and 1981-82 recessions) and the exceptional (about 5 percent) decline that we observed instead.

In contrast to discretionary services, nondiscretionary services expenditures (not shown) fell less during the recent recession than they did in the early 1980s recession, primarily because real health care expenditures held up better in this recession. The exceptional weakness of services PCE in this recession thus appears to be a story of discretionary services.

How Weak Has the Recovery Been in Discretionary Services?

Next, I compare the behavior of real per capita discretionary services expenditures in this recovery to that in “fast” recoveries (the average of those following the 1973-75 and 1981-83 recessions) and in “slow” recoveries (the average of those following the 1980, 1990-91, and 2001 recessions). To do this comparison, the chart below displays an index of real per capita discretionary services expenditures that equals 100 for the quarter at the end of a recession (as determined by the National Bureau of Economic Research). Using this index, we then can evaluate how rapidly these expenditures have recovered since the end of the recession relative to previous economic expansions. This chart shows that the current “recovery” in these expenditures has been exceptionally sluggish, and even slower than that in previous slow recoveries. In fact, these expenditures in 2010:Q4—six quarters after the end of the recession—were still below their level at the trough! As such, these expenditures have been a major contributor to the overall sluggish recovery we have experienced so far.

Real-discretionary

What Should We Take from These Developments?

Because many of these expenditures can be deferred when economic conditions are strained (for example, eating at home rather than eating out, or passing on the visit to Disney World) and given the increasing share of services in the economy, discretionary services will remain a significant factor in business cycles. In the recent recession, the large rise in unemployment and the sharp drop in household wealth appear to have led households to reduce discretionary services expenditures to a greater extent than we have seen previously, as they attempted to maintain a smoother path of non-discretionary services expenditures.

However, the fact that discretionary services expenditures remain significantly below their previous peaks is of concern for the overall economic outlook. Although these expenditures can be deferred in instances of temporary income drops, the sluggish recovery in these expenditures suggests, consistent with the permanent income/life cycle hypothesis, that households may perceive more persistent shocks to their overall wealth. For example, homeowners may expect house prices to recover only slowly at best, and thus the decline in housing wealth to be more persistent. Also, households may remain wary about their employment and income prospects, suggesting that they may have lowered their future income expectations. Accordingly, the continued sluggishness of discretionary service expenditures at this point in the expansion lends a note of caution regarding the recently improved economic growth outlook.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author(s).

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

I agree with the life-cycle hyposthesis and the permanent income perceived change to explain why the consumer is more careful but I also suspect that reduced availability to credit might have reinforced the process.

The comments to this entry are closed.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives