Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

January 6, 2014

Are Economic Values Transmitted from Parents to Children?

Marco Cipriani, Paola Giuliano, and Olivier Jeanne

Economic research shows that differences in cultural traits and values—for example, trust, or the propensity to cooperate and not free-ride on others—are important determinants of economic
outcomes, such as growth, economic and financial development, and international trade. It’s much less clear, however, where these
differences in economic-relevant values come from. While economists generally
assume that they’re transmitted from parents to children, the empirical
evidence to this effect is almost nonexistent.


    
In a recently published paper, we tried to fill this gap by studying whether
economic-relevant attitudes of children resemble those of their parents. We focus
on what we call “pro-sociality,” that is, the importance attached to
contributing to a common good. In the study, a sample of children and their
parents play a public goods game—a standard way of measuring a person’s level
of “pro-social” behavior. We then compare the pro-sociality of the
children with that of their parents to see if they are related.

The Public Goods Game

In a public goods game, a
subject is assigned to a group of, for instance, four people. Each person in
the group is given some money, let’s say $1, and asked to share it between him
or herself and a group fund. Contributions to the group fund are multiplied by
two and divided equally between members of the group independently of how
much they contributed to the group fund
.

    
Of course, if all members
of the group keep their endowments for themselves, they each get to keep their
$1. In contrast, since contributions to the group fund are doubled, if each
member of the group contributes his or her endowment to the fund, each member ends
up with $2, which is a clearly superior outcome. Nevertheless, an individual’s
choice of how to behave in a public goods game is not a simple one. Let’s say that
you’re playing the game and all the people in your group contribute their $1
endowment. If you do the same, everyone ends up with $2. If, however, you
decide not to contribute, you keep your $1 and still receive $1.50 from the
group fund, leaving you with a total of $2.50. For you as an individual, not contributing to the fund is better than contributing.

    
In other words, in a
public goods game there’s a tension between what’s good for the group and what’s
good for the individual. Although it’s better for the group as a whole that
everyone contributes his or her own endowment, each member of the group
individually has an incentive to keep the endowment and free-ride on the
others. This problem is very similar to the decision of fixing the roof in an
apartment building: everyone enjoys the new roof, including those who didn’t
contribute to it; as a result, everyone has an incentive not to pay for the
roof repairs and let the neighbors fix it.

    
Public goods games have been studied extensively by economists. They find that individuals usually contribute between 40 and 60 percent of the maximum amount ($1 in our example), depending on how the game is implemented. Because contributing has a positive effect on the group as a whole, an individual’s contribution can be taken as an indicator of his or her pro-sociality.

    
The behavior of both
children and parents in the new study was similar to that found in previous work:
parents contributed 58 percent of the maximum amount, and children contributed
just slightly less, at 55 percent. However, was the behavior of the children similar
to that of their parents? In other words, was there evidence from how the game was
played that pro-sociality is transmitted from parents to children?

Like Mother Like Son?

The answer is no. The data don’t show any correlation between a parent’s contribution and that of his
or her child. In other words, there’s no evidence that pro-social behavior is
transmitted from parents to children. This finding is robust to several
specifications that we used to analyze the data.

    
Of course, many caveats are in order. It’s possible that abstract games like the one we used aren’t the best way of capturing people’s attitudes toward contributing to a public good. The sample we studied (children in a Washington, D.C., public school and their parents) may not be representative, and different results may be obtained when looking at different segments of the population. Partial understanding of the game by young children may have also confounded the results.

    
Nevertheless, the absence of transmission of economic-relevant values from parents to children is very surprising. An unchallenged assumption in the economic literature on values and economic outcomes is the idea that the family has an important role in transmitting these values across generations. Our results provide an important piece of evidence to the contrary, which calls for further work on the issue.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.


Cipriani_marco

Marco Cipriani is a senior economist in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Paola Giuliano is a professor of economics at the University of California, Los Angeles.

Olivier Jeanne is a professor of economics at Johns Hopkins University.

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

Age might also come into play (it might be covered already, but I have not read the whole paper). It might be that the evolution of the attitude towards a public good over time trumps the direct transmission mechanism. There might also be a cohort effect that needs to be controlled for.

This is not surprising when you look at more recent psychology research that challenges the notion that mothers are most important for shaping children. It’s the peer group that dominates, especially after age 6. Just think about it – children of immigrants do not pick up their parent’s accents and cultural traditions. They adopt their peer group’s. This is what will lead an individual to the greatest chance of life success.

My own experience and casual observation is that parents’ financial behavior (thrift or indulgence) is observed and repeated by children when grown up. This might be better studied by examining credit ratings and debt by generation.

The comments to this entry are closed.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives