Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

January 13, 2014

Discount Window Stigma

Olivier Armantier

One of the main missions of central banks is to act as a lender of last resort to the banking system. In the United States, the Federal Reserve has relied on the discount window (DW) for nearly a century to fulfill this task. Historically, however, the DW has been little used even when banks may have faced acute liquidity shortages, a phenomenon commonly attributed to stigma. In this post, we show that during the last financial crisis banks were willing to pay large premia to avoid borrowing from the DW, suggesting that DW stigma is an economically important phenomenon.


 
 
 
 
DW stigma is generally defined as banks’ reluctance to approach the DW out of concerns that, if detected, depositors, creditors, or analysts could interpret DW borrowing as a sign of financial weakness. It is believed that such inferences could have severe consequences for DW borrowers such as a run on deposits, a loss of confidence by market analysts, a drop in the institution’s stock price, or a withdrawal of market sources of liquidity. The economic consequences of DW stigma may be particularly severe during financial crises, preventing the Fed from effectively disseminating liquidity when it is most needed. In addition, a bank that delays accessing the DW may resort instead to costly alternatives (such as fire sales of assets), which may further weaken the bank and add to financial system instability. Finally, a reluctance to borrow at the DW could lead banks to excessively self-insure against tail risks, thereby reducing the loans it extends to other financial firms and to the real economy.

 
 
 
 
In a previous post, we looked at DW stigma with respect to the Term Auction Facility (TAF), a temporary facility introduced in December 2007 by the Fed as an alternative to the DW. The TAF was specifically designed as an auction to remove perceptions of stigma that had plagued the DW. We found that between December 2007 and October 2008 banks were willing to pay a substantial premium—in excess of 44 basis points on average—to borrow from the TAF instead of the DW. However, because the TAF was operated under similar conditions to the DW, we cannot exclude the possibility that, despite the Fed’s effort, the TAF was also stigmatized. In other words, it is possible that banks preferred not to borrow from the Fed at the TAF out of concern about being perceived as financially weak. In this case, our initial measures of the magnitude and costs of DW stigma would be underestimated. As a follow-up to our initial study, we consider an alternative measure of the magnitude of DW stigma by calculating the premia banks were willing to pay in short-term funding markets to avoid borrowing at the DW.

 
 
 
 
The main challenge when juxtaposing DW and market borrowing is to identify markets that offer funding with comparable terms. Perfect substitutes do not exist, since the lenders (the Fed in the case of the DW and private institutions in the case of the financial markets) have different objectives. Nevertheless, we argue in our paper that two markets, the tri-party repo (“repo”) and asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) markets, offered reasonable substitutes to the DW with respect to the borrower’s eligibility, the collateral used to secure the loans, and the terms of the loans offered. We can then define the DW stigma premium with respect to these markets as the difference between their rates and the DW rate, which is equal to the Fed’s target rate plus a penalty spread.

 
 
 
 
Between December 2007 and October 2008, the average DW stigma premium relative to the TAF, the ABCP market, and the repo markets were very similar at 44, 42, and 47 basis points, respectively. In the days immediately after the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers, the stigma premium with respect to the ABCP and repo markets jumped to around 120 basis points, similar to the sharp rise in the DW stigma premium with respect to TAF.

 
 
 
 
The similarity among the three measures of DW stigma may be better appreciated in the chart below where the average DW stigma premia with respect to the TAF (blue line), the repo market (green line), and the ABCP (red line) market are plotted (with observations marked by squares, circles, and diamonds, respectively). The three measures of DW stigma premium generally followed a similar pattern: they were low between January 1, 2008, and March 16, 2008 (when the DW penalty spread over the target rate was reduced), became elevated, but relatively stable following this period until the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers, and rose sharply in the days thereafter. There are, however, two noticeable differences between the three measures: the ABCP-based DW stigma premium was relatively high in December 2007, while the repo-based DW stigma premium was lower in the weeks before the failure of Lehman Brothers. The first difference was likely due to the sharp increase in ABCP yields during the run on the ABCP market in December 2007. The second difference may reflect the impact of the Fed’s Term Securities Lending Facility intended to reduce stresses in the repo market.

Ch1_dw-stigma

 
 
 
 
Now, are there differences with respect to the opportunity cost of DW stigma? To address this question we calculated how much more a bank actually paid in interest by borrowing at the TAF, on the ABCP market, and on the repo market instead of borrowing an equal amount at the DW. In the left panel of the next chart, we can see, on average, a bank would have saved a substantial amount (between $34 million and $62 million per quarter depending on the source of funding) by borrowing at the DW. Note also that the DW stigma opportunity cost is the largest with respect to the ABCP market reflecting the fact that ABCP issuers are mostly big banks with sizeable ABCP issuances.

 
 
 
 
In the right panel, the opportunity costs are expressed in relative terms, that is, as a percent of the amount of interest the bank would have had to pay if it had borrowed at the DW. An interesting aspect of this relative measure is that it is directly comparable across the three funding sources as it does not depend on the amount borrowed. The opportunity cost relative to interest payments is relatively large and remarkably similar across the TAF, ABCP, and repo borrowing, measuring between 11.7 percent and 14.3 percent.

<a class="asset-img-link" style="display: inline;"
Ch2_opportunity-costs

 
 
 
 
In summary, our results show that banks could have lowered their interest expenses substantially during the financial crisis of 2007 and 2008 by borrowing from the DW instead of from the TAF or from the financial markets. We also find that the magnitude and opportunity cost of DW stigma was remarkably similar whether banks borrowed from the Fed, at the TAF, or from private institutions in the ABCP and repo markets. In particular, we do not identify a downward bias in our estimates of the DW stigma premium with respect to the TAF, consistent with the idea that the TAF was effectively designed to eliminate the stigma of borrowing from the Fed.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author.


Armantier_olivier
Olivier Armantier is an assistant vice president in the Research and Statistics Group of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives