Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

August 18, 2014

Gates, Fees, and Preemptive Runs

Marco Cipriani, Antoine Martin, Patrick E. McCabe, and Bruno Parigi

In the academic literature on banks, “suspension of convertibility”—that is, preventing the exchange of deposits at par for cash—has traditionally been seen as a potential means of preventing economically damaging bank runs. In this post, however, we show that giving a financial intermediary (FI) the option to suspend convertibility may ultimately increase the risk of runs by causing preemptive runs. That is, investors who face potential restrictions on their future access to cash may run when they anticipate that such restrictions may be imposed.


    This insight is relevant for policymaking in today’s financial system. For example, in July 2014, the Securities and Exchange Commission adopted rules that are intended to reduce the likelihood of runs on money market funds (MMFs) by giving the funds’ boards the option to halt (or “gate”) redemptions or to charge fees for redemptions when liquidity runs short, actions analogous to suspending the convertibility of deposits into cash at par. Our results show that the option to suspend convertibility has important drawbacks: A bank, MMF, or other FI with the option to suspend convertibility may become more fragile and vulnerable to runs. In other words, we show that instead of offering a solution, policies relying on gates and fees can be part of the problem.

Preemptive Runs
To formalize the intuition for why gates or fees may trigger runs, we consider a four-period model of the economy, as outlined in the exhibit below. Investors deposit money with the FI at date 0, for example, in the form of demand deposits that can be withdrawn at par or MMF shares redeemable at $1 each. The FI invests part of this money in a relatively illiquid asset—a bank might make a loan, while an MMF might purchase commercial paper—that matures at date 3. The FI’s investment offers a positive rate of return that the FI can pass along to investors who withdraw at date 3. However, if investors withdraw before date 3, the FI incurs a substantial cost in liquidating the investment.

A Three-Period Financial Economy

    Consider what happens if uncertainty suddenly develops about the return on the FI’s investment. In particular, suppose that, at date 1, a portion of the FI’s investors—call them “informed”— learn that the FI’s investment returns are more volatile than originally thought. Let’s also assume that both the FI and the informed investors will learn at date 2 whether the FI’s investment has actually soured.

    At date 1, the informed investors have a choice. They can immediately redeem to obtain their cash, which would force the FI into a costly liquidation of the investment. Alternatively, they can wait for the uncertainty to be resolved, since a favorable outcome for the FI’s investment will allow them to obtain a positive return at date 3.

    For the FI and the economy as a whole, having investors wait is clearly better. This would avoid costly liquidation and allow for the possibility that the investment might turn out to be profitable, in which case everyone will be (ex post) better off waiting until date 3.

    In fact, we show that under fairly general conditions, if the FI cannot suspend convertibility by imposing gates or fees on redemptions, informed investors will optimally decide not to run at date 1. Instead, they will wait until uncertainty is resolved at date 2, because waiting may allow them to partake of the positive return on the FI’s investment if it turns out to be profitable. After all, these investors would still have the option of redeeming at date 2 if they learn that the FI’s investment has turned out to be bad.

    But what happens if the FI can impose a gate or fee at date 2? We show that if the FI’s investment turns out to be bad, the FI will exercise its option to impose gates or fees on investors at date 2. In this case, informed investors may obtain less than what they originally deposited with the FI, because they must share the loss with the FI’s other investors. This risk causes informed investors to run preemptively from the FI at date 1 in anticipation of the possibility that convertibility may be restricted at date 2.

Conclusions
We prove these points more formally in a recent Federal Reserve Bank of New York staff report. There, we use a traditional model of financial intermediation to demonstrate the basic proposition discussed in this post: Giving an FI the option to impose gates or fees may be destabilizing because the option itself can trigger damaging runs that otherwise would not have occurred. This result is likely to hold for a variety of adjustments to the assumptions in our model, because the intuition is stark: The possibility of a fee or any other measure that is costly enough to counter investors’ strong incentives to run amid a crisis will give investors a strong incentive to run preemptively to avoid such measures.

    Even though our model does not address how runs on FIs can create large negative externalities for the financial system and the real economy, one important policy implication is clear: Giving FIs, such as MMFs, the option to restrict redemptions when liquidity falls short may threaten financial stability by setting up the possibility of preemptive runs.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.


Cipriani_marco
Marco Cipriani is a research officer in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

  Martin_antoine
Antoine Martin is a vice president in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

  Mccabe_patrick
Patrick E. McCabe is a senior economist in the Division of Research and Statistics at the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

  Parigi_bruno
Bruno Parigi is a professor of economics at the University of Padua.

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

Bail-ins. Negative interest rates. Now gates and fees. These transfer risk to the investor, and transfer trust away from the institution and the regulator. Seems only logical the dynamic, intelligent investor must re-price that new risk and trust. If gated, a money market becomes a time fixed bond, requiring compensation for the time. If price is allowed to float, the account becomes a risk asset, requiring compensation for the risk.

Although the post above provides an interesting theoretical insight, the discussion brings to mind the quote by Yogi Berra that, “In theory, there is no difference between theory and practice. But in practice, there is.” In practice, fees and gates are just one aspect of the nuanced package of money market fund reforms that the SEC adopted in July 2014 after long study. It is curious that the blog post fails to mention that the SEC’s new rule also requires institutional money market funds to float their net asset values (NAVs), a reform that the 12 Federal Reserve bank presidents—including William Dudley, the president of the New York Federal Reserve—said would address run risk. If this is true, then it is unclear that a floating-NAV fund would ever need to impose fees and gates. For other reasons why fees and gates are unlikely to cause runs, please see this blog post by ICI economists Sean Collins and Chris Plantier: http://www.ici.org/viewpoints/view_14_theory_practice_gates

The comments to this entry are closed.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives