Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

October 18, 2018

Bank‑Intermediated Arbitrage

LSE_2018_Bank-Intermediated Arbitrage

Since the 2007-09 financial crisis, the prices of closely related assets have shown persistent deviations—so-called basis spreads. Because such disparities create apparent profit opportunities, the question arises of why they are not arbitraged away. In a recent Staff Report, we argue that post-crisis changes to regulation and market structure have increased the costs to banks of participating in spread-narrowing trades, creating limits to arbitrage. In addition, although one might expect hedge funds to act as arbitrageurs, we find evidence that post-crisis regulation affects not only the targeted banks but also spills over to less regulated firms that rely on bank intermediation for their arbitrage strategies.

Basis Trades and their Regulation

The law of one price—that a replicating portfolio producing the same payoff as an underlying asset be priced the same as the underlying asset—is one of the fundamental tenets of finance. Prolonged periods when the prices of related assets significantly deviate from each other therefore suggest “limits to arbitrage”—the inability of investors to eliminate mispricing through spread-narrowing trades.

For example, in the chart below we compare spreads on credit default swaps (CDS) with spreads on the corresponding corporate bonds. The blue area in the chart shows the difference in the spreads, referred to as the CDS-bond basis. This mispricing is exploited in a classic “arbitrage trade,” where an investor buys a corporate bond and simultaneously buys CDS protection on the bond when the basis is negative (in other words, when the price of credit risk is cheaper in the bond market than in the CDS market), or sells the bond and sells the CDS when the basis is positive (see Section 2.3 of our paper for details). Before the 2007-09 financial crisis, the basis tended to be slightly positive, which was then attributed to the cost of shorting a bond; since the crisis, the basis has been persistently negative for the majority of CDS-bond pairs, which might be associated with the increased capital cost of banks holding bonds on their balance sheets. Similar patterns hold for basis spreads in a number of other asset classes.


Bank-Intermediated Arbitrage

Might these deviations from parity persist because post-crisis regulations have increased the cost of participating in spread-narrowing trades for banks? To answer this question, we need to consider the effects of post-crisis regulation on the different elements of a basis trade.

Consider again the CDS-bond basis trade and assume that a bank wants to exploit a negative basis by buying a bond and buying a CDS. The long position in the corporate bond would be financed through a repurchase agreement (repo), with the bank borrowing cash and posting the corporate bond as collateral. The position in the single-name CDS requires funding only for the margin requirement on the contract and the fair value of the contract, both of which would usually be funded in the unsecured funding market. Thus, the overall profit of the CDS-bond basis trade depends on the CDS-bond basis net of the interest paid on the corporate bond repo and the cost of financing repo haircuts (if any), CDS margin, and CDS fair value. (In a repo, the haircut is the value of the collateral in excess of the value of the cash exchanged.)

Under the pre-crisis regulatory regime, the repo position in the corporate bond affected the duration of the bank’s liabilities but did not impact its Tier 1 capital requirements. Thus, the only impact of the trade on the Tier 1 capital requirements was through recognition of the potential future exposure of the CDS position.

In contrast, under the post-crisis regime, the supplementary leverage ratio (SLR) requires that banks recognize the full notional amount of the repo position. Thus, every dollar of trade exposure in the CDS-bond basis is reflected as more than one dollar of exposure on a regulated institution’s balance sheet, limiting its ability to participate in the trade.

Arbitrage Activity and Profitability for Regulated Institutions

In our paper, we document the components of typical basis trades across a number of markets—U.S. interest rates, foreign exchange, and U.S. credit. Most of the trades that we describe have at least one component that is a cash product—funded through the repo market—and one component that is a derivative. Thus, changes in the regulatory environment that discourage banks from participating in either repo or derivatives markets also discourage these banks from participating in spread-narrowing trades.

As an example, the chart below shows a measure of activity in derivatives markets—the gross notional amount outstanding in U.S. dollar equivalents for interest rate, foreign exchange, credit, equity, and commodity over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives. While the exponential pre-crisis growth in activity has slowed considerably post-crisis, we see a marked decline coinciding with the post-2014 period when many new regulations such as the SLR and liquidity coverage ratio were being implemented.


Bank-Intermediated Arbitrage

More specifically, we show in our paper that U.S. global systemically important banks (G-SIBs), subject to the strictest post-crisis regulations, have indeed adjusted their repo and derivatives market activities since 2014. In particular, U.S. G-SIBs have significantly reduced their activity in repo markets relative to the pre-crisis period and to non-G-SIB banks. In derivatives markets, we find that changes in the gross notional amount outstanding of non-centrally cleared OTC derivatives are positively correlated with the gross notional amount traded between dealers. Moreover, for interest rate and foreign exchange derivatives—some of the derivatives most affected by post-crisis regulations—the positive correlation has become stronger since the regulations came into effect around 2014.

In addition to these quantity measures, we also calculate the return on equity (ROE) that a bank can achieve on a basis trade, accounting for the regulatory treatment of all of the components of the trade under both the pre-crisis and post-crisis regulatory environments. The next chart compares the average ROE for CDS-bond basis trades under risk-weighted assets (RWA) with the average ROE under SLR constraints. For a detailed description of these measures as well as ROE measures for other basis trades, see Section 4 of our paper.


Bank-Intermediated Arbitrage

As the chart indicates, the ROE is significantly lower under the SLR constraint relative to both the RWA constraint and to the 10-15 percent ROE that most large banks target. Even though basis spreads have frequently been larger post-crisis than pre-crisis, regulatory changes imply that the basis trades are not sufficiently profitable from the perspective of regulated institutions, even at these elevated levels.

Why Don’t Nonbank Arbitrageurs Step In?

The question, then, is why less regulated arbitrageurs such as hedge funds don’t substitute for banks’ lower arbitrage activity. Our hypothesis is that, to the extent that arbitrageurs rely on regulated institutions for funding, clearing, and execution services, even nonregulated arbitrageurs may be affected by post-crisis regulations.

Consistent with this hypothesis, we find evidence that levered funds using G-SIB prime brokers have been differentially affected in recent years. The next chart shows that among funds that use a G-SIB prime broker, assets under management (AUM) for levered funds have declined significantly more in recent years than for unlevered funds.


Bank-Intermediated Arbitrage

The next chart shows that, among levered funds, aggregate AUM for funds that use a G-SIB prime broker has declined significantly more than funds that do not use a G-SIB prime broker, a result that reflects the declining number of levered funds using G-SIB prime brokers.


Bank-Intermediated Arbitrage

Finally, we show in our paper that performance has also been affected. Alongside the overall decline in hedge fund performance in recent years, levered funds using G-SIB prime brokers have underperformed relative to unlevered funds using G-SIB prime brokers on a value-weighted basis.

Summing Up

Taken together, our results suggest both a direct effect of regulation as well as a pass-through effect from the directly affected banks to other parts of the financial sector that rely on the regulated sector for intermediation. Of course, the costs of these limits to arbitrage must be weighed against the increased resiliency of both the regulated sector and the financial system as a whole, factors that are not addressed in our paper.

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.


Nina BoyarchenkoNina Boyarchenko is a senior economist in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Thomas M. EisenbachThomas M. Eisenbach is a senior economist in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

Pooja GuptaPooja Gupta is an analyst in the Bank’s Markets Group.

Or ShacharOr Shachar is an economist in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

Peter Van TasselPeter Van Tassel is an economist in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

How to cite this blog post:

Nina Boyarchenko, Thomas M. Eisenbach, Pooja Gupta, Or Shachar, and Peter Van Tassel, “Bank-Intermediated Arbitrage,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics (blog), October 18, 2018, http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2018/10/bank-intermediated-arbitrage.html.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives