Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

September 12, 2011

Can Speculative Trading Magnify Financial Market Co‑movement?

Christian Grisse

Global financial markets tend to move together. For example, stock market movements across the globe are highly synchronized, economic data releases frequently have large spillover effects across borders, and episodes of financial turmoil often spread across countries that share no significant economic linkages. The degree of co-movement across markets often appears to be surprisingly large when compared with the strength of the underlying economic relationships. What can explain this seemingly “excessive” co-movement? This post, based on a recent research paper, argues that speculative trading may magnify financial market co-movement.


     Intuitively, the price of a financial asset should be related to its fundamental value. For example, I am willing to pay more for a stock if I expect to receive high dividends in the future. In this case, the value of dividends would be one fundamental factor determining the price. One would then expect the degree to which prices of financial assets move together to be related to the correlation of their underlying fundamental factors. However, a number of empirical studies have argued that the co-movement between stock markets, bond markets, and commodity markets may be larger than that justified by underlying fundamental linkages. One aspect of this finding is the observed large cross-border impact of economic data releases. For example, a recent IMF working paper documents significant spillover effects of credit rating announcements across countries.

    If fundamental factors are unable to account fully for the observed magnitude of financial market co-movement, how could speculation—the buying and selling of financial assets in anticipation of future price movements—help to explain co-movement? The key point to understand is that in contrast to long-term investors, speculators need to take into account the expectations of others. Speculators buy an asset today in the hope that they will be able to re-sell it later at a higher price. Thus, when deciding whether to purchase the asset today, speculators need to form expectations about tomorrow’s price. But tomorrow’s price will in turn depend on expectations tomorrow—averaged across investors—about prices two periods ahead. It follows then that today’s price, which depends on speculators’ demand for the asset, will be determined by the market’s expectation today of the market’s expectation tomorrow, of the market’s expectation two days ahead, and so on, of the fundamental value of the asset. In short, prices are determined by “higher order expectations,” averaged across all market participants, of “fundamentals.”

    The British economist John Maynard Keynes described this situation in his well-known “beauty contest” analogy:

Professional investment may be likened to those newspaper competitions in which the competitors have to pick out the six prettiest faces from a hundred photographs, the prize being awarded to the competitor whose choice most nearly corresponds to the average preferences of the competitors as a whole; so that each competitor has to pick, not those faces which he himself finds prettiest, but those which he thinks likeliest to catch the fancy of the other competitors, all of whom are looking at the problem from the same point of view. (The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, London: Macmillan, 1936, p. 156)

    Similarly, speculators don’t care which financial asset has the highest value in the long run, but instead care which financial asset other investors think has the highest value—because it is these assets which will go up in price in the short run. Speculators are therefore forecasting the forecasts of others, a problem first analyzed rigorously by Robert Townsend. The consequence is that prices are determined not by average expectations of fundamental asset values, but instead by average expectations of future average expectations, and so forth, of asset values. A key insight—see, for example, an article by Franklin Allen, Stephen Morris, and Hyun-Song Shin that appeared in the Review of Financial Studies—is that such average higher order expectations of fundamentals generally differ from average expectations of the fundamentals.

    To see this, consider a long-term investor who evaluates the sustainability of government finances using two sources of information: a public forecast of the fiscal position that has just been published by a ratings agency, and his own private assessment. The statistically optimal forecast takes into account both the investor’s own information and the rating agency’s projection—in particular, it is a weighted average of the two, with weights that correspond to the degree of confidence the investor has in the two sources of information. Now consider a speculator who forecasts tomorrow’s price for government bonds using the same information. The speculator knows that everybody in the market has observed the projection published by the ratings agency and will thus react to it. In contrast, his own personal assessment—while possibly just as well informed as the rating agency’s forecast—is known only to him. Therefore, while both forecasts may have a similar value for assessing the government’s fiscal situation, the public forecast is more useful for predicting the market reaction, and thus tomorrow’s prices. It follows that when investors speculate on future price developments, they will place a larger weight on public news of a ratings downgrade and a smaller weight on their own private information than would be the case if they were forecasting fundamentals—in this example, the government’s fiscal position—directly. Consequently, prices will “overreact” to the ratings agency’s publication: the announcement will have a larger impact on prices than on the market’s assessment of the country’s fiscal position.

    To see the implications of speculation for financial market co-movement, consider government bonds in two countries, A and B, and suppose that the countries share some economic linkages. For example, business cycles could be connected through international trade, which would imply a relationship for the dynamics of governments’ fiscal positions as well. Because of the assumed underlying fundamental link, a credit rating announcement for country A also provides information about country B’s fiscal situation—even though it is obviously a less precise signal for forecasting developments in country B. The same logic of speculation and higher order expectations applies: because the credit rating news is observed by all market participants, individual speculators will find it more useful than their own private assessment in forecasting tomorrow’s price for the government bonds of country B. Consequently, the market as a whole will place a larger weight on the public information “credit rating downgrade,” and the prices of government bonds in both A and B will “overreact” to the announcement. Thus, speculation can potentially magnify asset price co-movement and information spillovers across borders.

    To conclude, economic theory suggests that speculation can magnify financial market co-movement. The key conditions for this amplification effect are that (1) there is some (possibly very weak) fundamental link across markets, which makes news releases in one market useful for forecasting fundamentals in the second market, and (2) speculators care about other investors’ assessment of asset values. What is the magnitude of this “overreaction” to public information? Because theoretical models of these effects are necessarily very stylized, bringing the model to the data is challenging. One implication of the theory, however, is that these effects should be larger in markets that are dominated by traders with short investment horizons. Furthermore, to the extent that the importance of speculation increases over time relative to the prevalence of long-term investment strategies, one would expect the magnitude of co-movement to increase.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this blog are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author(s).

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives