Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

April 18, 2014

How Liquidity Standards Can Improve Lending of Last Resort Policies

João A.C. Santos and Javier Suarez


This post is the sixth in a series of six Liberty Street Economics posts on liquidity issues.

Prior to the Great Recession, the focus of bank regulation was on bank capital with little consensus about the need for liquidity regulation. This view was in contrast with an existing body of academic research that pointed to inefficiencies in environments with strictly private provision of liquidity, via either interbank markets or credit line agreements. In spite of theoretical results pointing to the possible benefits of liquidity regulation for reducing fire sales in crises or the risk of panics due to coordination failures, a common view was that its costs might exceed its benefits, especially given a situation in which there is an active lender of last resort (LLR).


    
The liquidity problems that banks experienced during the recent financial crisis convinced policymakers about the need for some form of liquidity regulation for banks. Banks’ liquidity problems appear to have started in the summer of 2007 following the collapse of the asset-backed commercial paper market. These problems grew worse with the collapse or near collapse of several other markets, including the repo and the financial commercial paper markets, and even several segments of the interbank market, and with banks’ collateral shortages arising in part from downward spirals in market and funding liquidity.

    
These problems also motivated new academic research on bank liquidity standards. This research, however, does not provide a clear reason for the dominance of liquidity standards such as the liquidity coverage ratio (LCR) of Basel III over alternatives like capital requirements, Pigovian charges for liquidity risk, or just the effective provision of emergency liquidity by the LLR. In a recent paper, we help close this gap in the literature with a theory that relies on a novel way of thinking about a liquidity requirement—an instrument that, by making banks better able to withstand the initial phases of a crisis, gives the LLR time to ascertain the potential implications of an early, disorderly liquidation of a bank in trouble.

    
We consider a model in which liquidity crises may cause banks to fail unless they are able to borrow from the LLR. In making a lending decision, the LLR faces the classical problem that some of the banks seeking liquidity support may be fundamentally insolvent. While it is optimal to grant liquidity to solvent banks, in the case of an insolvent bank, LLR support may still make sense if the negative externalities that will arise with the bank’s early liquidation are sufficiently large. Yet assessing these externalities in real time is quite difficult. Following this view, we assume that the LLR is generally uncertain about the extent of the external costs of an early liquidation, but that the presence of liquidity standards increases the likelihood of the LLR knowing whether its decision to deny liquidity support will lead to a systemic crisis. The idea is that liquidity standards, by lengthening the time a bank can withstand a liquidity shock, give the LLR more “breathing room” to find out the systemic implications of a bank’s default.

    
In our setting, liquidity standards affect both the ex post (that is, after the crisis begins) efficiency of LLR policies and bankers’ adoption of precautions against a crisis. Our model shows that liquidity standards are beneficial from both perspectives when banks are ex ante considered likely to be systemically important, but only from the first point of view (and counterproductive to the second one) when banks are ex ante considered unlikely to be systemically important. The intuition for this result is that, if the presence of systemic banks is highly likely, an uninformed LLR will end up supporting any bank in trouble, which augments banks’ prospects of being supported in a crisis and thus erodes their incentives to prevent a crisis. Liquidity standards help the LLR discover insolvent banks that are actually not systemic and, hence, can be denied support, which is good from the perspective of reducing banks’ moral hazard problem.

    
In light of this insight, the lessons of the Lehman Brothers debacle about the relevance of systemic externalities and the concerns about the moral hazard implications of implementing too-generous support policies in future crises can rationalize the importance of liquidity standards. Buying the time needed to make better informed support decisions will not only improve the efficiency of the ex post decisions, but it will also reduce banks’ prospects of unconditional support in a future crisis and the moral hazard problem associated with such support. Our paper is also novel in providing a framework in which one can analyze the implications of identifying systemically important financial institutions ahead of time.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.


Santos_joao

João A.C. Santos is a vice president in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Javier Suarez is a professor of finance at Universidad Carlos III de Madrid.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives