Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

May 4, 2016

Why Dealers Trade in GCF Repo®

Editors’ note: The original version of this post had the terms “borrowers” and lenders” reversed and had some figures wrong. The corrected figures do not suggest, as before, that dealers who switch between borrowing and lending are pursing collateral swapping strategies. We regret the error. (August 16)

LSE_2016_GCF-repo-series-3_460_art


In this post, the third in a series on GCF Repo®, we describe dealers’ trading strategies. We show that most dealers exhibit highly regular strategies, using the GCF Repo service either to borrow or to lend, on net, on almost all the days in which they are active. Moreover, dealers’ strategies are highly persistent over time: Dealers that use GCF Repo to borrow (or to lend) in a given quarter are highly likely to continue to do so in the following quarter. Understanding how dealers trade in the GCF Repo market may provide insight about the role of the repo market more generally and about how recent regulations and market reforms can affect dealers’ trading strategies.


Background

The GCF Repo service, offered by the Fixed Income Clearing Corporation (FICC), allows dealers to exchange government securities for cash among themselves anonymously, with FICC as a central counterparty.

Dealers enter into GCF Repo contracts for various reasons, including raising funds, obtaining collateral, and providing transactional liquidity in the repo market. A previous LSE post describes dealers’ strategies at an aggregated level, showing that dealers affiliated with a bank holding company act differently, as a group, than unaffiliated dealers; in contrast, our work focuses on individual dealers, and the persistence of their GCF Repo market trading strategy.

Borrowers and Lenders

Using confidential GCF Repo data from the first half of 2015, we study whether dealers are consistently borrowing or lending cash (against securities) on net. We label dealers as “borrowers” if they are net borrowers of cash on at least 95 percent of the days in which they are active. Similarly, dealers are labeled as “lenders” if they are lending cash, on net, on at least 95 percent of the days in which they are active. Dealers that don’t fit into either category, and so have a mix of borrowing and lending, are labeled as “mixed.”

As seen in the table below, of the fifty-seven dealers active in GCF Repo over our sample period, eleven are classified as lenders and twenty-nine as borrowers. Only seventeen dealers pursued mixed strategies, where their net positions varied between borrowing and lending cash.


LSE_2016_GCF-repo-series_dealers-trade-3_cipriani_table1B_revised0815_art

To measure the importance of a dealer’s net position to its total gross activity, we compute each dealer’s net-to-gross ratio and take the average for each group of dealers. Net activity is the sum of cash borrowed (a positive number) and cash loaned (a negative number) by a dealer in a day, and gross activity is the sum of the absolute value of cash borrowed and cash loaned. Borrowers’ mean net-to-gross ratio is 0.66, which means that 66 percent of borrowers’ total activity in GCF Repo is attributable to borrowing. By this measure, then, borrowers’ other strategies in GCF Repo take a backseat to raising funds. Similar results are found with lenders—80 percent of lenders’ activity is attributable to lending.

Finally, we measure the size of borrowers and lenders and find that these two groups account for the majority of GCF Repo gross activity; borrowers’ share of total gross activity is 44 percent and lenders’ share is 21.5 percent.

We also repeat our analysis above for a given asset class. We focus on the two asset classes that dominate GCF Repo activity—U.S. Treasuries, and Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac fixed-rate mortgage-backed securities. We find that the same general pattern discussed above continues to hold: For a given asset class, borrowers and lenders account for the majority of activity, both in terms of the number of dealers and as a percentage of activity.


LSE_2016_GCF-repo-series_dealers-trade-3_cipriani_table2_revised0815_art

Persistence of Funding Strategy

We now turn to examining the persistence of dealers’ trading strategies in GCF Repo. The table below reports the frequency with which a borrower remains a borrower, becomes a lender, or becomes unclassified (mixed) between two given quarters during the period October 2012 to September 2015. As the second row of the table shows, 93 percent of borrowers in a given quarter remain borrowers in the following quarter; analogously, 81 percent of lenders remain lenders and 63 percent of mixed remain mixed. In other words, over our sample period, we find that dealers follow highly persistent strategies. Strikingly, lenders never switched to become borrowers from one quarter to the next and, similarly, borrowers switched and became lenders only 0.3 percent of the time.


LSE_2016_GCF-repo-series_dealers-trade-3_cipriani_table3_revised0815_art

Takeaways

We show that the majority of individual dealers follow consistent strategies in GCF Repo, where dealers are net borrowers or lenders on almost every day that they are active. Moreover, dealers’ strategies are highly persistent over time: Dealers that use the facility to borrow (or to lend) one quarter are very likely to do so the next.

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.



Marco CiprianiMarco Cipriani is an officer in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Adam CopelandAdam Copeland is also an officer in the Group.

How to cite this blog post:

Marco Cipriani and Adam Copeland, “Why Dealers Trade in GCF Repo®,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics (blog), May 4, 2016, http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2016/05/why-dealers-trade-in-gcf-repo.html.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives