Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

November 16, 2016

Escaping Unemployment Traps

LSE_2016_Escaping Unemployment Traps

Economic activity has remained subdued following the Great Recession. One interpretation of the listless recovery is that recessions inflict permanent damage on an economy’s productive capacity. For example, extended periods of high unemployment can lead to skill losses among workers, reducing human capital and lowering future output. This notion that temporary recessions have long-lasting consequences is often termed hysteresis. Another explanation for sluggish growth is the influential secular stagnation hypothesis, which attributes slow growth to long-term changes in the economy’s underlying structure. While these explanations are observationally similar, they have very different policy implications. In particular, if structural factors are responsible for slow growth, then there might be little monetary policy can do to reverse this trend. If instead hysteresis is to blame, then monetary policy may be able to reverse slowdowns in potential output, or even prevent them from occurring in the first place.


We created a theoretical model to investigate this issue. A crucial assumption underlying the model is that workers lose human capital while unemployed and that it is costly for firms to retrain unemployed workers. (There is a large empirical literature documenting the scarring effects of unemployment; see, for example, these papers by Wee and Song and Wachter.) The potential for skill loss generates multiple possible long-run outcomes, or steady states. One favorable steady state corresponds to a high-pressure economy with high job-finding rates, low unemployment, and new hires requiring little training. However, the economy can also be trapped in an undesirable steady state, corresponding to a low-pressure economy with low job-finding rates, high unemployment, and a significant loss of human capital. Crucially, in the absence of nominal rigidities, and in the absence of external shocks, both steady states will persist, with a low-pressure economy never able to transition to a high-pressure economy.

To study the effect of monetary policy under such circumstances, we assume that that there is some form of nominal rigidity in the economy—namely, that nominal wages are sticky (as documented empirically in a 2016 paper by Fallick, Lettau, and Wascher, among many others). The assumption that nominal wages adjust slowly allows monetary policy to influence economic activity. We then proceed to evaluate two monetary policy regimes. The first is a price level target (PLT) that keeps prices at a level consistent with a high-pressure economy. The second is a “neutral” monetary policy, which seeks to maintain the level of output that would exist if wages were flexible. The key difference is that neutral monetary policy allows for higher prices than PLT, and so provides more stimulus after a deep recession.

Using the model, we find that these two policy rules engineer a swift recovery to the high-pressure steady state in response to small temporary shocks. This isn’t surprising since a substantial literature in monetary economics argues that policies promoting price stability have desirable outcomes. However, we find that these rules may fail to restore the economy to full employment when faced with large shocks.

Under price level targeting, a large negative shock causes prices to fall, increasing real wages and reducing hiring. The fall in hiring, in turn, lengthens the average duration of unemployment and reduces human capital. Even after the shock dissipates, it is costly for firms to retrain workers who lost human capital. Temporarily lower real wages (that is, higher prices) could compensate firms for these training costs and stimulate hiring. A price level target, however, does not permit enough of a rise in prices, causing a permanent decline in hiring and employment. It is worth noting that this result runs counter to a large literature that finds that PLT performs very well (relative to inflation targeting) in many circumstances (see also this 2013 blog post). In particular, in a liquidity trap, PLT is more expansionary than inflation targeting, because it commits to reverse the fall in inflation that occurs during the downturn. PLT does all of these things in our model—but in the presence of hysteresis, even PLT is not expansionary enough.

Neutral monetary policy fares only slightly better. Recall that this policy seeks to replicate outcomes that would arise in an economy with flexible wages. After the initial shock, this policy rule recognizes that potential output is lower, and raises prices accordingly. However, this monetary policy generates at best a slow recovery, and at worst, permanent stagnation. While it permits a larger rise in prices than PLT, the increase is still not enough to generate a speedy recovery.

In an economy vulnerable to hysteresis, monetary policy rules that fare well in normal times can lead to pathological outcomes when faced with large shocks. Alternative rules can do better. Forward guidance—specifically, a commitment to deliberately overshoot the inflation target, even once the economy has returned to full employment—can mitigate deflationary pressures during the recession and moderate employment losses. Thus, a monetary policy stance that is more accommodative than neutral monetary policy may be able to avert unemployment traps altogether.

Of course, the best way to escape unemployment traps is to avoid entering them in the first place. However, this may not be very useful advice for economies already dealing with stagnation. Is there anything that can be done in these cases? In other words, is the damage from an unemployment trap reversible? It depends. A commitment to keep prices elevated for an extended period of time may boost hiring until the economy returns to full employment. Just as recessions damage potential output, booms can repair it. However, this only works to the extent that monetary policy can create a boom, and not just avert a recession. Another possibility is that after some point, additional monetary stimulus only leads to higher prices without increasing economic activity. If this is in fact the case, then monetary policy cannot engineer hiring booms and is powerless to help the economy escape an unemployment trap. Other measures, such as fiscal policy, would then be required. This suggests that it becomes all the more important to prevent the economy from entering such a trap in the first place, and lends support to the view that the risks associated with monetary easing are asymmetric. That is, excessive easing can be reversed, but excessive tightening may cause irreversible damage to the economy’s potential output.

In the research described in this blog, we focus on the effect of recessions on human capital. Recessions may affect potential output through other channels as well, such as lower capital accumulation, lower labor force participation, slow productivity growth, and so forth. Our research would suggest that to the extent that these mechanisms are operative, a monetary policy that seeks to track measured natural rates—of unemployment, interest rates, and so forth—might be insufficiently accommodative to engineer a full and quick recovery after a large recession. Such policies fall short because in a world with hysteresis, “natural” rates are endogenous. Policy should set these rates, not track them.

Whether or not hysteresis is severe enough to support such a conclusion is ultimately an empirical question. It is particularly important to ascertain whether secular stagnation or hysteresis is responsible for sluggish growth, because while they are observationally similar, the two warrant very different policy prescriptions.

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.



Sushant AcharyaSushant Acharya is an economist in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Julien Bengui is an assistant professor of economics at Université de Montréal.


Keshav Dogra
Keshav Dogra is an economist in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

Shu Lin Wee is an assistant professor of economics at the Carnegie Mellon Tepper School of Business.

How to cite this blog post:

Sushant Acharya, Julien Bengui, Keshav Dogra, and Shu Lin Wee, “Escaping Unemployment Traps,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics (blog), November 16, 2016, http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2016/11/escaping-unemployment-traps.html.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives