Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

November 10, 2020

The Fed Funds Market during the 2007‑09 Financial Crisis

The U.S. federal funds market played a central role in the financial system during the 2007-09 crisis, because it was the market which provided banks with immediate liquidity, even late in the day. Interpreting changes in fed funds rates is notoriously difficult, however, as many of the economic drivers behind the rates are simultaneously changing. In this post, I highlight results from a working paper which untangles the impact of these economic drivers and measures their respective effects on the marketplace using data over a sample period leading up to and during the financial crisis. The analysis shows that the spread between fed funds sold and bought widened because of increases in counterparty risk. Further, there was a large increase in the supply of cash into this market, suggesting that banks viewed fed funds as a relatively safe place to invest cash in a crisis environment.

What happened to fed funds rates and quantities over the 2007-09 crisis?

The fed funds market is an ideal laboratory to study liquidity issues that were central to the 2007-09 crisis. To illustrate the key economic forces at play during the crisis, I examine daily rates and quantities of fed funds purchased and sold, as well the spread between these two rates.

The data used in the analysis are the fed funds sales and purchases of three large banks that were considered major players in the market for fed funds from January 2006 to December 2008. Importantly, the data cover both the pre-crisis and crisis periods and allow me to construct both average rates and total quantities of fed funds purchased and sold.

Befitting their intermediary status, these three banks consistently sold fed funds at rates higher than at which they purchased them. This intermediary spread averaged 11 basis points in the pre-crisis period, from January 2006 through July 2007. Starting in August 2007, this spread jumps up to 26 basis points, a 15 point increase. Finally, the spread rockets up to 118 basis points after the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers in September 2008. This evolution in the intermediary spread is illustrated in the chart below.


The Fed Funds Market during the 2007-09 Financial Crisis

Strikingly, the total amount of funds intermediated by the three banks increases with the onset of the crisis, despite the increases in the intermediary’s spread (see the chart below). Between the start of the crisis and the Lehman bankruptcy, the average total daily amount intermediated is 42 percent greater than the figure for the pre-crisis period ($2.7 billion versus $1.9 billion). Even after the Lehman bankruptcy and the subsequent disruptions to the overall financial system, the total amount of fed funds intermediated by the three banks is 11 percent greater than in the pre-crisis period.


The Fed Funds Market during the 2007-09 Financial Crisis

How do we interpret these changes in rates and quantities?

To better understand the various drivers behind these movements in rates and quantities, I develop a model of the fed funds market and take it to the data. I find the model fits the data well, and the estimated parameters have two main implications. First, there is a steady increase in market participants’ beliefs about the probability of default by banks borrowing in the fed funds market. Although it is well-known that market participants’ concerns about default were heightened with the crisis, this analysis is able to precisely estimate this risk. The model implies that with the start of the crisis in August 2007, the expected probability of default by a borrowing bank increases from 0.043 percent to 0.333 percent, and then leaps up to 2.24 percent after the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers.

Second, the parameter estimates imply that the supply of fed funds shifted out over the crisis. In particular, there were large increases in the supply of fed funds both starting in the summer of 2007 when the crisis first began and after the Lehman bankruptcy. This result is noteworthy, because of the prevailing belief that the supply of fed funds declined over the crisis. Instead, the estimated parameters imply that banks’ options of investing cash elsewhere in the financial system became increasingly less attractive over the course of the crisis. This accords with what is known about other financial markets collapsing, such as the freezing up of the asset-backed commercial paper market in late 2007.

The model then shows that the increase in fed funds supply was particularly crucial to the vitality of the fed funds market. It predicts that if fed funds supply had not increased, then the increase in expected default would have caused the fed funds market to freeze up.

What does this mean for market participants and policymakers?

There are two lessons from this analysis. First, policymakers should be aware that the fed funds market is susceptible to small changes in the expected probability of default. Hence, future adverse events which cause banks to become more prone to default are likely to have large negative effects on this market. Second, the fed funds market is considered to be a safe place to invest cash, relative to the other money markets, during a crisis. Given a general adverse shock to the financial system then, policymakers can expect depository institutions to shift their cash investments towards the fed funds market. Even though the fed funds market has changed somewhat since the 2007-09 crisis, it remains an important part of the financial system and so these results are still relevant.


Adam Copeland
Adam Copeland is an assistant vice president in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

How to cite this post:

Adam Copeland, “The Fed Funds Market during the 2007-09 Financial Crisis,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics, November 10, 2020, https://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2020/11/the-fed-funds-market-during-the-2007-09-financial-crisis.html.


Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives