Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

June 29, 2016

Monetary Policy Transmission before and after the Crisis

LSE_Monetary Policy Transmission before and after the Crisis

The Federal Open Market Committee implements monetary policy by raising or lowering its target for the federal funds rate, the interest rate banks charge each other for overnight loans. Because the Federal Reserve has no direct control over most interest rates, it relies on arbitrage in money markets for the change in the fed funds rate to be transmitted to other short-term rates, thus causing all short-term rates to move in tandem. This transmission to other rates is an important first step for the Fed’s actions to influence the real economy. In this post, we describe the major developments that have affected monetary policy transmission since the recent financial crisis. We conclude that while arbitrage may have been impeded at the beginning of the crisis, it currently remains effective in transmitting changes in monetary policy via the money markets.

Recent Developments in Monetary Policy Implementation

Before the financial crisis, bank reserves were relatively scarce—that is, the amount of reserves in the banking system was close to the amount that banks were required to hold. Further, since banks received no interest on the reserves held at the Fed, they tried to minimize their holdings. Instead, if they needed reserves (for example, to meet a payment), banks would borrow them in the fed funds market. The New York Fed’s trading desk adjusted the total supply of reserves in the banking system to keep the market or “effective” rate of the fed funds close to the target rate. Since some of the banks that traded in the fed funds market were also active in other money markets, they had incentives to keep rates aligned through arbitrage.

In the chart below, we plot the effective fed funds rate and overnight general collateral repo rate over a six-year period encompassing the financial crisis. The fed funds rate and the repo rate co-moved tightly before the crisis, as would be expected if arbitrage kept these rates aligned. Once the crisis started, however, the repo rate became volatile and often deviated from the fed funds rate, suggesting that monetary policy transmission may have been impaired.

LSE_Monetary Policy Transmission before and after the Crisis

The Fed implemented extraordinary measures during the crisis to ensure the soundness of the financial system and to stimulate the economy. In particular, the Fed provided liquidity assistance to financial institutions and implemented the large-scale asset purchase (LSAP) program. These programs entailed a substantial increase in reserves as liabilities to back up these assets. Since the quantity of reserves was well above required reserves, banks no longer faced a strong trade-off between holding reserves and selling them in the fed funds market. To maintain an incentive for banks to hold reserves, the Fed paid interest on reserves (IOR) from October 2008 onwards. This was meant to create a “floor” for the fed funds rate since no bank should be willing to lend reserves at a rate below the IOR rate.

The Fed also repeatedly reduced the fed funds target rate until it reached a range of 0 to 25 basis points (the zero lower bound or ZLB) in December 2008. It remained in this range until “liftoff” in December 2015, when the Fed increased the target range for the first time since the crisis.

Contrary to expectations, the fed funds rate traded well below IOR in the post-crisis period (see the chart below). This was due in part to segmentation in the fed funds markets whereby government-sponsored enterprises, such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, who were active lenders in the fed funds market, were not eligible to receive IOR and thus were willing to lend fed funds at rates lower than IOR. Moreover, various regulations may have increased banks’ costs of engaging in arbitrage activities and thereby helped to keep the fed funds rate below IOR.

Also during the post-crisis period, the repo rate frequently exceeded the fed funds rate even though repo borrowing is secured while fed funds are not. This could be indicative of frictions in money markets, and could also be related to a Fed program that increased the demand for repo financing.

LSE_Monetary Policy Transmission before and after the Crisis

In order to set a harder floor for short-term rates and to improve arbitrage between money markets, the Fed began testing a new tool in September 2013, the overnight reverse repurchase agreement (ONRRP) facility, where eligible counterparties provide overnight loans to the Fed secured by collateral from the Fed’s securities portfolio. This new facility is open to a broad set of financial counterparties (including nonbank entities such as mutual funds) and therefore has not suffered from the same segmentation issues as IOR.

The Efficacy of Monetary Policy Transmission since 2002

For monetary policy transmission to be effective, information about fed funds rate changes should be quickly conveyed to other money market rates (such as for repo borrowing). This section investigates whether that is the case, despite the many changes to the money markets since the crisis.

To compare the dynamics of fed funds and repo rates before and after major developments in money markets, we consider their movements relative to the target rate. Since there were several target rate changes in the pre-crisis period but none during the ZLB period, we measure rates as deviations from the target rate in order to make the rate dynamics more comparable. We exclude from our analysis the crisis period of 2007-08 due to the extreme market stress at this time as well as the period from November 2015 onward since the markets were already anticipating “liftoff.” We analyze the following periods: the pre-crisis (2002-06) and the ZLB periods (January 2009-October 2015) with the latter divided into pre-ONRRP (January 2009-August 2013) and post-ONRRP (September 2013-October 2015) periods.

On average, the fed funds and repo rates remained within the target range even during the ZLB period (see the left panel in the chart below). However, this is not necessarily evidence of effective monetary policy transmission but instead might reflect natural features of the financial system that prevent nominal interest rates from becoming negative. There also appears to be a reduction in the absolute spread between the fed funds rate and the repo rate in the post-crisis period, a fact which seems counterintuitive since the higher credit risk in the post-crisis period would be expected to result in higher spreads between the secured and unsecured rates. The right panel below reveals a dramatic reduction in volatility of rates, particularly the repo rate, after the introduction of the ONRRP program.

LSE_2016_policy-transmission_sarkar_ch3_art

To evaluate the strength of transmission statistically, we test whether past values of the fed funds rate predict the current repo rate. The results in the table below show that the fed funds rate predicts the repo rate (indicating that the Fed’s monetary policy decisions were transmitted to the repo market) in both the pre-crisis and post-ONRRP periods. In the pre-ONRRP period, however, the fed funds rate does not significantly predict the repo rate, suggesting that transmission may have been impaired between the fed funds and repo markets during this period.

LSE_Monetary Policy Transmission before and after the Crisis

Since the results suggest that arbitrage picked up after introduction of the ONRRP facility, we estimate whether the speed of arbitrage was indeed faster during the post-ONRRP period. We posit that there is an equilibrium relationship between the fed funds and repo rates in the long run, but that the rates may deviate from the equilibrium relationship in the short run. Since there are no arbitrage opportunities when the rates are in the long-run equilibrium, the number of days the repo rate takes to revert to equilibrium after the fed funds rate changes may indicate the speed of arbitrage. We utilize a vector error correction model that estimates both the long-run equilibrium relationship between the fed funds and repo rates and also how quickly they return to the equilibrium path after deviating from it. We find that, in the pre-ONRRP period, it took about three weeks for the repo rate to return to equilibrium versus two weeks in the post-ONRRP period. In other words, misalignment of rates persisted for longer periods of time in the pre-ONRRP period, and arbitrageurs more rapidly corrected deviations in the post-ONRRP period.

LSE_Monetary Policy Transmission before and after the Crisis

Implications for Monetary Policy Transmission

Despite substantive changes in the monetary policy framework and in money market conditions since the financial crisis, arbitrage currently appears to be effective in transmitting changes in monetary policy from the fed funds market to other money markets. While arbitrage may have been hampered initially during the ZLB period, it seems to have revived after the ONRRP facility was introduced. One explanation for the revival of arbitrage may be the ability of the ONRRP facility to reduce uncertainty in rates by setting a harder floor for short-term interest rates. Thus, the continued operation of this new facility appears to be important for efficient money market functioning and monetary policy transmission.

The authors thank Domenico Giannone for extensive advice, comments, and help.

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.



Kroeger_alex
Alexander Kroeger is a senior research analyst in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Sarkar_asani
Asani Sarkar is an assistant vice president in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Integrated Policy Analysis Group.

How to cite this blog post:
Alexander Kroeger and Asani Sarkar, “Monetary Policy Transmission before and after the Crisis,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics (blog), June 29, 2016, http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2016/06/monetary-policy-transmission-before-and-after-the-crisis.html.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives