Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

June 30, 2017

The Role of Central Bank Lending Facilities in Monetary Policy

Editor’s note: This post was originally published on June 30, 2017. We are running it again today, August 14, in conjunction with a companion piece scheduled for August 16. An error in the table was corrected on July 3.

LSE_The Role of Central Bank Lending Facilities in Monetary Policy

Central bank lending facilities were vital during the financial crisis of 2007-08 when many banks and nonbank financial institutions turned to them to meet funding needs as private funding dried up. Since then, there has been renewed interest in the design of central bank lending facilities in the post-crisis period. In this post, we compare the Federal Reserve’s discount window with the lending facilities at three other major central banks: the Bank of England (BoE), the European Central Bank (ECB), and the Bank of Japan (BoJ). We observe that, relative to the other central banks, the Fed’s discount window is less integrated into the monetary policy framework. In a follow-up post, we will discuss differences in the central banks’ counterparty and collateral policies.

What Is a Standing Lending Facility?

We use “standing lending facility” (SLF) to refer to a facility that lends on a bilateral and on-demand basis rather than in the open market through scheduled auctions. The Fed’s discount window—namely the primary credit program—is an example of an SLF. As shown in the table below, SLFs go by different names: at the ECB, it is called the marginal lending facility and, at the BoJ, the complementary lending facility. The BoE uses two SLFs—the operational SLF (OSLF) and the discount window facility (DWF). The OSLF, which usually lends overnight, is used for monetary policy purposes, while the DWF lends on a longer-term basis and serves a financial stability purpose. We do not discuss emergency lending facilities since these only lend in crisis situations, and are typically designed as open market auction-based facilities rather than on-demand bilateral lending facilities.

While normally considered a financial stability tool, SLFs usually also serve a monetary policy role (see table). In their monetary policy role, SLFs limit upward pressure on interest rates by providing loans to individual institutions that might occasionally experience urgent funding needs. As such, SLFs may be used to set a ceiling in the interest rate corridor, as discussed below. In addition, most SLFs have a financial stability purpose, providing credit to the financial sector broadly during crises. In this post, we focus on the SLF’s role in maintaining the interest rate corridor, where there is a difference between the Fed’s discount window and the SLFs of the other central banks.

The Role of Central Bank Lending Facilities in Monetary Policy

Standing Lending Facility Rates as Corridor Ceilings

Frameworks for implementing monetary policy are typically either corridor-type or floor-type systems, depending on the method used for keeping the overnight, interbank interest rate close to the central bank’s target.

The BoE, ECB, and BoJ have long maintained interest rate corridors. The rate on the SLF acts as the ceiling of the corridor because, in theory, no banks should be willing to borrow at a higher rate in private funding markets. The interest rate paid by central banks at their standing deposit facility (SDF), where banks can deposit excess funds overnight, should act as the floor of the interest rate corridor (because, in theory, no banks should be willing to lend at a rate below the SDF rate). Thus, the SLF and SDF are integral parts of the monetary policy framework of the three central banks.

In contrast to the other three central banks, the Fed’s discount window has been less integrated into the monetary policy framework. This difference is partly because the Fed’s use of an interest rate corridor is more recent. Before 2003, there was no policy rate that acted as a ceiling on interest rates, since the discount window rate was kept below the federal funds target rate. This is because the discount window was intended to provide subsidized loans to institutions with temporary funding pressures. Since 2003, the rate on discount window lending—the primary credit rate—has been set above the target federal funds rate. Even so, the discount window rate has not functioned as a ceiling (with market rates often exceeding the primary credit rate) due to the stigma of borrowing from the discount window.

While the Fed has never maintained an SDF whose rate might serve as a corridor floor, in 2008 it began paying interest on reserves that banks deposit at the Fed. In theory, banks should not lend at a rate lower than the interest on reserves. In practice, the interbank rate has often traded below the interest on reserves, as some lenders are not eligible to earn interest on reserves with the Fed.

In the original Federal Reserve Act of 1913, the discount window was the only monetary policy tool, but its role in monetary policy began to decline soon thereafter. From the 1920s onward, open market operations (OMOs), involving purchases and sales of securities in the open market, became the Fed’s central monetary policy tool. Since their inception, OMOs have been successful in keeping the overnight rate close to the Fed’s target, even when interbank markets were highly volatile. It is only in recent years that the Fed has begun to adopt elements of a formal corridor system (in particular, interest on reserves).

It’s More about the Floor Since the Crisis

As overnight rates have hovered close to zero since the crisis of 2007-08, all four central banks have focused more on the floor rather than the ceiling on overnight rates. The traditional interest rate corridor continues to be maintained at the three foreign central banks, though the ECB has shifted to the use of the standing deposit rate as its main policy rate. At the Fed, a new tool (overnight reverse repos) has been implemented to help support the floor for the federal funds rate, and it appears to have been effective in keeping that rate within the target range. In our next post, we compare the counterparty and collateral policies of the Fed’s discount window with those of the other three central banks’ SLFs.

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.



Helene LeeHelene Lee is a senior associate in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Markets Group.

Asani SarkarAsani Sarkar is an assistant vice president in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

How to cite this blog post:

Helene Lee and Asani Sarkar, “The Role of Central Bank Lending Facilities in Monetary Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics (blog), June 30, 2017, http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2017/06/the-role-of-central-bank-lending-facilities-in-monetary-policy.html.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives