Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

July 8, 2016

Hey, Economist! Why—and When—Did the Treasury Embrace Regular and Predictable Issuance?

LSE_Why—and When—Did the Treasury Embrace Regular and Predictable Issuance?

Few people know the Treasury market from as many angles as Ken Garbade, a senior vice president in the Money and Payments Studies area of the New York Fed’s Research Group. Ken taught financial markets at NYU’s graduate school of business for many years before heading to Wall Street to assume a position in the research department of the primary dealer division of Bankers Trust Company. At Bankers, Ken conducted relative-value research on the Treasury market, assessing how return varies relative to risk for particular Treasury securities. For a time, he also traded single-payment Treasury obligations known as STRIPS—although not especially successfully, he notes.


As an economist at the Fed, Ken has sought to combine his academic and practical backgrounds by researching and writing about the history of the Treasury market. His book Birth of a Market: The U.S. Treasury Securities Market from the Great War to the Great Depression was published by MIT Press in 2012; his latest work, Treasury Debt Management under the Rubric of Regular and Predictable Issuance, was released by the Bank last fall.

Publications editor Valerie LaPorte spoke with Ken about his interest in the Treasury market and his new book.

Q: To many people, the Treasury market seems obscure. What makes it so worthy of study?

A: The Treasury market provides the U.S. government with its principal means of funding federal budget deficits. It’s also an important source of liquidity for investors who generally need to invest over predictable intervals but whose needs may change before their investments mature. And, of course, it’s the principal locus of Federal Reserve open market operations.

Q: Your new book looks at the evolution of a particular Treasury practice—the issuance of securities in predictable amounts at regular intervals. Those who follow Treasury auctions might assume that Treasury securities were always issued in this way. But as you show in your book, this was not always the case.

A: That’s right. The Treasury initiated regular auction offerings with weekly 13-week bill auctions in 1937, and moved to regular auctions of 26-week and 1-year bills in the late 1950s. However, until the 1970s, it issued notes and bonds—its longer-term obligations—through fixed-price subscription offerings on an “as needed” basis. The Treasury scheduled the offerings to meet its funding requirements but offered maturities that investors were interested in buying at the time.

Q: What drove the Treasury to adopt regular and predictable issuance of notes and bonds in the 1970s?

A: The lack of predictability left many intermediate- and long-term investors with little incentive to accumulate funds in anticipation of an offering at a desirable maturity—who knew when it might come to market? The uncertainty also placed a significant underwriting burden on primary dealers.

When interest rates became more volatile in the early 1970s—and as the size of the federal deficit and the frequency and size of Treasury offerings began to grow—Under Secretary of the Treasury Paul Volcker, who would later become the president of our Bank and then chairman of the Board of Governors, realized that it would be less costly to issue notes, and later bonds, on a regular and predictable basis and to auction those securities as it auctioned bills. Regularity meant that investors could plan ahead; auctions reduced the risk that an offering would fail to attract adequate interest.

Q: If the Treasury had many years of experience auctioning bills on a regular and predictable basis, why did it take so long to extend the practice to notes and bonds?

A: My best guess, and it’s only a guess, is that change and innovation are uncomfortable in the absence of a demonstrated need. The changed conditions of the 1970s produced the requisite need. The fresh outlook of a new Treasury under secretary undoubtedly helped as well.

Q: Have circumstances required the Treasury to depart from this practice at times? What were the consequences?

A: The Treasury departed from the practice twice—in the sale of foreign-targeted notes in the mid-1980s, and in the sale of bills for the Supplementary Financing Program following the onset of the financial crisis in 2008. In the first case, Treasury officials thought they could get cheaper funds by issuing opportunistically; in the second, officials had to respond to the exigencies of the crisis. The foreign-targeted program was a failure and was canceled after four offerings. SFP issuance proved more lasting, but was converted to a regular and predictable schedule in 2009 as funding requirements stabilized, and later eliminated when the funds were no longer needed.

Q: Given that Treasury financing needs rise and fall with the business cycle, how has the Treasury been able to maintain its reputation for regular and predictable issuance?

A: The historical record suggests that Treasury has maintained its enviable reputation as a regular and predictable issuer by limiting revisions of offering schedules and amounts to those times when fluctuations in federal financing requirements clearly demand a change, and to revisions that clearly reduce aggregate funding costs without substantively altering investment opportunities. An example of the second type of change is the Treasury’s 1986 decision to cancel the 20-year bond series and to replace it with expanded offerings of 10-year notes and 30-year bonds that nicely bracketed the terminated series.

Q: The musical “Hamilton,” which focuses on the first U.S. Treasury secretary, may be generating new popular interest in this area of the government. What first interested you about the workings of the Treasury?

A: The New York Fed has long-standing and extraordinarily deep ties to the Treasury market, as Treasury’s agent in primary market sales and in its role managing open market operations for the other Reserve Banks and the Federal Open Market Committee. There were gaps in our understanding of the evolution of the market that I was quite happy to fill. My research has taken me to the Treasury’s own archives, to contemporary news accounts, and to the reports and meeting minutes of the Treasury Borrowing Advisory Committee. I’ve found it gratifying to help document and preserve a rich administrative legacy that has so benefited the country in war and peace.

—Valerie LaPorte

Further Reading: Posts by Ken Garbade on Treasury Topics

“The Evolution of Federal Debt Ceilings,” November 14, 2011

“Innovations in Treasury Debt Instruments,” April 9, 2012

“How the Nation Resolved its First Debt Ceiling Crisis,” March 4, 2013

“Direct Purchases of Federal Reserve Securities by Federal Reserve Banks,” September 29, 2014

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author.



Kenneth Garbade
Kenneth D. Garbade is a senior vice president in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

How to cite this blog post:
Kenneth D. Garbade, interview by Valerie LaPorte, “Hey, Economist! Why—and When—Did the Treasury Embrace Regular and Predictable Issuance?” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics (blog), June 24, 2016, http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2016/07/hey-economist-whyand-whendid-the-treasury-embrace-regular-and-predictable-issuance.html.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives