Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

February 7, 2022

The Future of Payments Is Not Stablecoins

Stablecoins, which we define as digital assets used as a medium of exchange that are purported to be backed by assets held specifically for that purpose, have grown considerably in the last two years. They rose from a market capitalization of $5.7 billion on December 1, 2019, to $155.6 billion on January 21, 2022. Moreover, a market that was once dominated by a single stablecoin—Tether (USDT)—now boasts five stablecoins with valuations over $1 billion (as of January 21, 2022; data about the supply of stablecoins can be found here). Analysts have started to pay increased attention to the stablecoin market, and the President’s Working Group (PWG) on Financial Markets released a report on stablecoins on November 1, 2021. In this post, we explain why we believe stablecoins are unlikely to be the future of payments.

Money vs Exchange Mechanism

As noted in this Liberty Street Economics post, it is useful to make a distinction between “money”—the asset that is being exchanged—and the “exchange mechanism”—that is, the method or process that transfers the asset. A key innovation of cryptocurrencies is that they operate on distributed ledger technology (DLT) platforms, a new type of exchange mechanism. In this post, we use the term “DLT platforms” to refer to payment systems involving this exchange mechanism.

Initially, the only assets circulating on DLT platforms were cryptocurrencies, such as Bitcoin or Ether. Over time, however, it became clear that these assets are too volatile to be used as payment instruments (as noted here, for example). Stablecoins were created in part to be a better form of money than other cryptocurrencies.

The Best Money on the Best Exchange Mechanism

Whether DLT platforms will come to dominate existing exchange mechanisms is open to debate. DLT platforms could improve on existing exchange mechanisms if, for example, they facilitate the use of new innovations, like smart contracts, or the creation of new types of financial intermediaries, like automated market makers. Nevertheless, important limitations, including scalability, could limit the usefulness of DLT platforms.

In this post, we don’t take a stance on whether DLT platforms are better. Instead, we ask: If DLT platforms are here to stay, what is the best possible money that can be used as a means of payment on that transfer mechanism? We offer three key reasons why the answer is unlikely to be “stablecoins.”

1. Stablecoins tie up liquidity unnecessarily.

Some policy makers now seem to be converging toward the idea that only a digital coin that is 100 percent backed by perfectly safe and liquid assets is viable. However, such a design may be a double-edged sword. On the one hand, it should help limit credit and liquidity risk to stablecoin holders, so long as there is legal and operational certainty that the liquid assets will remain available to meet the claims of these holders. On the other hand, tying up safe and liquid assets in a stablecoin arrangement means they are not available for other uses, such as helping banks satisfy their regulatory requirements to maintain sufficient liquidity, for example. This could lead to disruptive shortages of safe and liquid assets.

2. Stablecoins that do not tie up liquidity are risky and less fungible.

As argued by Held and then Gorton and Zhang, stablecoins resemble historical private bank notes, particularly those issued during the Free Banking Era in the United States. Without the regulatory framework and safeguards put in place to support bank deposits, these types of private monies were subject to various problems, notably because issuers and the assets backing them were of uncertain and divergent quality. Consequently, private bank notes were not fungible and individuals handling them needed to consider whether to accept any particular note at face value. Given that similar economic mechanisms underlie private bank notes and stablecoins, history suggests that stablecoins might suffer from problems similar to those of private bank notes during the Free Banking Era.

3. We already have an efficient form of digital money; we just need to adapt it to a new environment.

Central bank actions over the last century have resulted in a well-functioning banking and payment system. Why not take advantage of that, and issue tokenized deposits? While a number of practical details would need to be worked out, the principle behind tokenized deposits is straightforward. Bank depositors would be able to convert their deposits into and out of digital assets—the tokenized deposits—that can circulate on a DLT platform. These tokenized deposits would represent a claim on the depositor’s commercial bank, just as a regular deposit does.

Recent analysis has emphasized the benefits of maintaining the centrality of banks in the payment system. As mentioned in this G7 report, one approach to “stabilizing the value of stablecoins is to leverage the financial strength and stability of the offering institution.” The PWG report on stablecoins recommends that they should be issued by insured depository institutions.

There are three reasons why it may be desirable to tokenize bank deposits. First, commercial banks hold deposits for customers that are fractionally backed by reserves, avoiding locking up liquidity. These bank deposits support bank lending to the real economy and the transmission of monetary policy.

Second, customers can exchange these deposits for goods or services using well-functioning existing payments infrastructures. Merchants receiving these funds through deposit-based payment systems do not worry about the source of these funds; they transfer at par. In this report, the Bank for International Settlements refers to this fungibility trait as the “singleness of the currency.” Singleness arises in part from the convertibility of commercial bank money into central bank money, something the U.S. regulatory and legal framework allows commercial banks to do with a high degree of certainty. The central bank’s role in this regard also creates a payment network that allows funds generated from multiple private sources to be exchanged seamlessly with significant economic benefits. Cheng and Torregrossa make a similar point.

Third, bank deposits have a number of other attractive features. They are issued by regulated institutions and are protected by deposit insurance (up to $250,000), which makes them extremely safe. In addition, banks facilitate compliance with policies meant to reduce the risk of criminal activities, such as money laundering.

Tokenized deposits may not be the only option that improves upon existing stablecoin offerings. But they provide a useful example of a better type of money that can, and does in limited capacities, circulate on a DLT platform. As such, they provide a realistic starting point to pursue that objective.

To Sum Up

The emergence of DLTs has led to a proliferation of new types of money, such as stablecoins, and other types of financial instruments, as in decentralized finance. In this post, we argue that if DLT platforms are the transfer mechanism of the future, then it seems worthwhile to find the best possible money that can be used on that transfer mechanism. We suggest that tokenized deposits might be a fruitful avenue to pursue.

Rod Garratt is a professor of economics at the University of California, Santa Barbara.

Michael Lee is an economist in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Antoine Martin is a senior vice president in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

Joseph Torregrossa is a vice president and associate general counsel in the Bank’s Legal Group.

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

This is basically a quick read on why stablecoins are a disruption to the status quo and why that status quo should be preserved. It’s impossible to read this as anything other than completely biased in favor of the existing system. At least you say the quiet part out loud when you get to “We already have an efficient form of money; we just need to adapt it.”

Tokenized deposits are exactly what a legitimate stablecoin should be. A stablecoin is either a money market mutual fund or a commodity fund, or both, depending on the assets held. No exemptions exist under either the Investment Company Act or Commodity Exchange Act and subsequent legislation, to operate or solicit unlicensed and unregistered funds.

#3 mentions tokenized deposits, which requires tying up liquidity…not much different than #1 except you give banks control of the liquidity. The whole point of Crypto is decentralization away from banks.

You are concerned about banks being able to meet their regulatory requirements to maintain liquidity. Meanwhile, those who deposit their money into a bank’s Savings account earn a measly 0.05% return per year.

Many of us are tired of those poor returns, and would rather leave the insured security of the banks behind, and do it ourselves. With money comes greed, and banks have their full share of both.

The comments to this entry are closed.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives