Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

November 26, 2012

Household Services Expenditures: An Update

Jonathan McCarthy

This post updates and extends my
July 2011 blog piece
 on household discretionary
services expenditures. I examine the most recent data to see what they reveal about
the depth of decline in expenditures in the last recession and the extent of
the recovery, and find that the expenditures appear to be further below the peak
identified earlier. I then compare the pace of recovery for discretionary and
nondiscretionary services in this expansion with that of previous expansions,
finding that the pace in both cases is well below that of previous cycles. In
summary, household spending continues to be constrained by a combination of
credit conditions and weak income expectations.


Depth of Decline
The chart below updates a similar chart from my previous post showing the
extent of the decline in real per capita discretionary services expenditures
from the previous peak. (A zero value in this chart and the following chart
indicates that expenditures were above their previous peak.) The differences
between this chart and the prior one result from two factors: the release of
data for additional quarters; and the revisions of previously released data.

    When we compare this chart with the companion
chart in the prior post, a couple of points are evident. First, the decline in
expenditures was much more severe in the 2007-09 recession than in the 2001 downturn;
moreover, the maximum decline of nearly 9 percent is considerably greater than
the estimated maximum decline using the data from early July 2011. Second, five
years after their peak, expenditures are still about 6.5 percent down (which is roughly similar
to the estimate of the maximum decline reported in my previous post).

Cumulative-Declines-in-Real-Discretionary-Services-PCE

    Offering another comparison, the
next chart presents the decline from the previous peak for the other portion of
services expenditures, which I label “nondiscretionary” services expenditures. (See
my prior post
for a definition of discretionary versus nondiscretionary expenditures.) As
seen in the chart, the fall in these expenditures in the past recession was
much less than the drop in discretionary services. In addition, while the
maximum decline in nondiscretionary services expenditures is large compared with
previous declines, it’s not unprecedentedly large, and these expenditures are above their prerecession levels, even though they have declined modestly in the second and third quarters of this year. These patterns indicate that, consistent with
the notions behind these labels, households responded to the severe income
declines of the recession by cutting back on spending on discretionary services
and by trying to maintain spending on nondiscretionary services.

Cumulative-Declines-in-Real-Nondiscretionary-Services-PCE

Pace of Recovery
I now examine the pace of recovery for discretionary services spending so
far in this expansion. To do so, I again update a chart from my prior post (showing
an index of real per capita discretionary services expenditures that equals 100
in the quarter at the end of a recession), which allows for a comparison of
this recovery with “fast” recoveries (the average of those following the
1973-75 and 1981-82 recessions) and “slow” recoveries (the average of those
following the 1980, 1990-91, and 2001 recessions). The chart below reveals that
the pace of recovery in the current cycle is still well behind that of previous
cycles. As of 2012:Q3, more than three years after the end of the last recession, discretionary
expenditures were only 1.6 percent above their level at the recession’s trough
(and there has been little change over the past year). In contrast, at this
point in the average slow recovery, these expenditures were 6.1 percent above
the level at the recessions’ trough; in the average fast recovery, they were 12.6 percent above their low point—and were also displaying
steady, solid increases at this stage of the cycle.

Real-Discretionary-Services-PCE-in-Recoveries

    Performing a similar exercise for nondiscretionary
services, I show that these expenditures also have been sluggish in this
expansion relative to previous expansions, even though they didn’t fall that
much during the last recession (see chart below). The level of these
expenditures in 2012:Q3 was 1.5 percent above the level at the last recession’s
trough, compared with 5.4 percent for the average slow recovery and 10.2 percent
for the average fast recovery at the same stage of the cycle.

Real-NondiscretionaryServices-PCE-in-Recoveries

Conclusion
The pattern of a similarly sluggish pace of recovery for discretionary and
nondiscretionary services expenditures suggests that the fundamentals for
consumer spending remain soft. In particular, it appears that households—more than three
years after the end of the recession—remain wary about their future income
growth and employment prospects even though consumer confidence measures have improved in recent months. In addition, households may still see the need
to repair their balance sheets from the damage incurred during the recession,
especially if they expect that increases in asset prices will be subdued at
best and that credit will continue to be constrained. Consequently, a positive
resolution of these issues is likely necessary before a stronger services and
overall consumer spending recovery can be sustained.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.


Mccarthy_jonathan 

Jonathan
McCarthy
is a vice president in the Research and Statistics Group of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

Have you ever thought about the impact of slower population growth and aging on the demand for both discretionary and non discretionary services. It can’t all be income, debt, and sentiment as you will find a much stronger rebound for very discretionary durable and nondurable goods.

The comments to this entry are closed.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives