Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

May 5, 2014

No Good Deals—No Bad Models

Nina Boyarchenko

The recent financial crisis has highlighted the significance of unhedgable, illiquid positions in complex securities for individual financial institutions and for the global financial system as a whole. Indeed, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision notes that

One of the key lessons of the crisis has been the need to strengthen the risk coverage of the capital framework. Failure to capture major on- and off-balance sheet risks, as well as derivative related exposures, was a key destabilizing factor during the crisis.


 
 
 
 
While concepts like marking-to-market and risk weighting of individual positions are incorporated in all three pillars of the Basel III capital regulation, the academic literature has lagged in providing a robust, model-free way of implementing these in practice. In a recent New York Fed staff report, my coauthors and I propose a methodology to compute lower and upper bounds on prices of complex, potentially nontraded securities that’s robust to possible misspecifications of cash flows to these securities. I review the main advantages of this approach in this post.

Good-Deal Bounds

Valuation of uncertain payoffs is the fundamental question of financial economics. If an illiquid asset’s payoffs were perfectly replicable by payoffs of a portfolio of liquid securities (whose prices can be observed directly), then the price of that asset could be computed as the price of the replicating portfolio. This is a direct consequence of the law of one price and the absence of arbitrage: A cash flow should be priced the same regardless of whether an investor receives it by investing in a single security or in a portfolio of securities. But when the uncertain payoffs of the asset in question cannot be perfectly replicated, the law of one price has very weak implications for the price of the asset. While absence of arbitrage arguments can be used to provide an upper bound (ask price) and a lower bound (bid price) on the price of the security, these bounds tend to be very wide for most securities of interest. This is the case with most derivatives – after all, if a derivative’s payoff were perfectly replicable with other liquid assets, there would be no reason for the derivative to exist – as well as for real assets, such as loans, held by financial institutions. In this case, additional restrictions are needed to narrow the distance between the bid and the ask price on the security.

 
 
 
 
Cochrane and Saa-Requejo (2000) introduce an economic consideration into the pricing of illiquid securities by restricting the maximum Sharpe ratio achievable by trading in a portfolio of both the liquid basis assets and the illiquid focus asset. The Sharpe ratio is the ratio between the expected return to a position and the standard deviation of the return, and is commonly used as a measure of how well the position compensates the investor for risk taken. Cochrane and Saa-Requejo (2000) argue that, just as arbitrage opportunities are ruled out for providing investors with a positive return for zero risk (effectively giving an infinite Sharpe ratio), high Sharpe ratios should also be ruled out for providing investors with unreasonably high returns for low levels of risk. If a strategy with a high Sharpe ratio were to exist, investors would want to follow the strategy in their trading, reducing the expected return and, thus, the Sharpe ratio of the strategy. The upper (ask price) and lower (bid price) valuations of illiquid securities should satisfy the same principles and thus be restricted from delivering “good deals” that violate the Sharpe ratio bound.

 
 
 
 
In our staff report, we introduce a second economic consideration into the pricing of complex securities – that investors’ decisions are robust to possible misspecification of the uncertainty structure of the focus asset’s payoffs. We assume that, while investors may have an estimate of the probability distribution from which asset payoffs are drawn, they recognize that their estimates may not reflect the true distribution. We assume that investors are averse to model uncertainty, and thus require that investors’ decisions be made using the worst-case distribution among the set of distributions that they consider. To find the worst-case distribution, the investor evaluates her utility under each distribution in the set of alternatives, and picks the distribution that delivers the lowest expected utility. As an investor’s degree of aversion to model uncertainty increases, the set of models considered by the investor increases as well. The exhibit below plots an investors’ utility as a function of the return relative to initial wealth, for three different levels of this aversion to model uncertainty. Since the investor picks the worst-case distribution, she places a higher probability weight on losses to her portfolio. As the investor’s degree of aversion to model uncertainty increases, so does the probability weight assigned to losses.

Chart1_Investors-Utility

 
 
 
 
Since the uncertainty-averse investor assigns higher probabilities to losses on the illiquid asset, the good-deal bounds are wider in the presence of model uncertainty than in its absence. Intuitively, if we interpret the lower bound on the price as the bid submitted by a buyer, an uncertainty-averse investor fears that the security is less valuable than predicted, and submits a lower bid. Similarly, the upper bound can be interpreted as the ask price of a seller, who fears that the security is more valuable than predicted. We show, moreover, that increased model uncertainty leads to fundamentally different bounds than an increase in the maximum Sharpe ratio. While the maximum Sharpe ratio restriction corresponds to a bound on the volatility of returns, aversion to model uncertainty introduces a consideration for negative skewness into the computation of lower and upper bounds on asset valuations. The resulting valuations are thus more conservative than the traditional good-deal bounds.


Model Uncertainty in the S&P 500


A key ingredient in computing the upper and lower bounds in the presence of model uncertainty is the degree of aversion to model uncertainty. In the staff report, we describe a procedure for estimating the degree of aversion to model uncertainty based on achieving a desired confidence level in the Sharpe ratio on the basis assets. Specifically, we randomly resample observed returns on the basis assets and compute the realized Sharpe ratio in each sample. We use the worst 80th percentile outcome as our Sharpe ratio bound under the worst-case measure, and solve for the degree of aversion to model uncertainty that corresponds to that Sharpe ratio bound. This makes the degree of aversion to model uncertainty market- and period-specific, which allows the degree of aversion to model uncertainty to respond to adverse market movements.

 
 
 
 
As an example of this estimation approach, we compute a real-time estimate of the degree of aversion to model uncertainty for an investor using the S&P 500 index and a risk-free bond as basis assets. The estimation is done using rolling, 600-trading-day observation windows. We then compare the evolution of the degree of aversion to model uncertainty with the evolution of the absolute value of the realized Sharpe ratio for the same observation period. The chart below shows that, for the S&P 500, the implied degree of aversion to model uncertainty is negatively related to the absolute value of the realized Sharpe ratio: Increases in the degree of aversion to model uncertainty coincide with decreases in the Sharpe ratio. Thus, an investor using the S&P 500 index and a risk-free bond as basis assets would become more averse to model uncertainty as the returns to holding the S&P 500 index become smaller, and would increase the bid-ask spread on any derivative whose risk of payoffs is correlated with the S&P 500.

Chart2_Relationship

Implications for Bank Regulation

The aftermath of the global financial crisis has intensified political and regulatory scrutiny of the hedging and risk management of over-the-counter derivatives, with special emphasis placed on mark-to-market (or mark-to-model) valuations. We propose the use of good-deal bounds computed in the presence of model uncertainty as fair reservation prices for complex, illiquid securities. Explicitly incorporating model uncertainty into fair reservation values recognizes the difficulty of assigning probabilities to infrequent large adverse moves. The use of Sharpe ratios as a valuation criterion simplifies the comparison of valuations across institutions: Since the basis assets are traded, their prices are observable and differences in valuations must thus arise from differences in either the maximum admissible Sharpe ratios or in aversion to model uncertainty. Mark-to-market valuations of complex securities could thus be standardized across institutions by requiring that a standard set of basis assets is used in conjunction with a common maximum Sharpe ratio bound and a common confidence level for the Sharpe ratio on the basis assets. As the realized Sharpe ratio on the basis securities evolves over time, this would introduce time variation in the implied degree of aversion to model uncertainty and thus to mark-to-market valuations.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author.


Boyarchenko_nina

Nina Boyarchenko is an economist in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives