Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

May 25, 2016

The Macro Effects of the Recent Swing in Financial Conditions

Credit conditions tightened considerably in the second half of 2015 and U.S. growth slowed. We estimate the extent to which tighter credit conditions last year were responsible for the slowdown using the FRBNY DSGE model. We find that growth would have slowed substantially more had the Federal Reserve not delayed liftoff in the federal funds rate.


The chart below shows the evolution of credit conditions, as measured by the spread between Baa yields and ten-year Treasury bond yields. One can see that spreads rose considerably from 2015:Q2 to 2016:Q1. This increase was largely unexpected. For instance, the FRBNY DSGE model was forecasting a modest decrease over the coming year as of 2015:Q2 (see the red line). The June 1, 2015, Blue Chip Financial Forecasts consensus was projecting essentially the same decline in spreads.

Credit Spread

Increases in credit spreads tend to be associated with subsequent slowdowns in economic activity, with the Great Recession being a salient example. In part, such increases reflect investors’ concerns about future economic conditions, changes in firms’ leverage, heightened worries about borrowers’ default, and so on. However, as Simon Gilchrist and Egon Zakrajšek and others have shown in their research, such increases in credit spreads often cause an economic slowdown. A natural question is then: Did the rise in credit spreads reflect deteriorating economic conditions or did the causality run the other way around in this episode?

To answer this question, we need an economic model that can disentangle the various channels at work. We use the FRBNY DSGE model, which is a very stylized representation of reality that formalizes key interactions among critical economic actors such as households, firms, the financial sector, and the government. The model is then estimated using Bayesian methods, combining prior information about parameters with important macroeconomic data.

The model attributes most of the increase in spreads from 2015:Q3 to 2016:Q1 to unexpected disturbances—which we will refer to as “financial shocks.” These shocks reflect developments that are not fully captured by the model. In late 2015, these developments include a downward revision in the foreign outlook and the deteriorating creditworthiness of the U.S. energy sector owing to the drop in energy prices.

How restrictive, then, has this rise in credit spreads been on the U.S. economy? The left panel in the next chart shows actual growth, from 2013:Q1 to 2016:Q1, in blue. After peaking at 3.9 percent (annual rate) in 2015:Q2, GDP growth slowed markedly for the subsequent three quarters, reaching a paltry 0.5 percent in 2016:Q1. Part of the slowdown was anticipated as of mid-2015: The red line, which indicates the 2015:Q2 forecast, shows that growth was expected to return to just below 2 percent. It just ended up being significantly lower.

real-gdp-growth

The right panel attributes the forecast “miss”—the difference between the blue and the red lines in the left panel—to the various sources of disturbance in the model. Focusing on the effects on growth of the tightening in credit conditions, the blue line in the right panel captures the contribution of the financial shocks that we discussed earlier. These shocks, which are behind the rise in credit spreads, subtracted more than a percentage point from growth (annualized) in each of 2015:Q3, 2015:Q4, and 2016:Q1.

Financial conditions loosened after February 2016, bringing credit spreads back down sharply. Thanks to this reversal in credit spreads, the restrictive effect on GDP growth in the current quarter (2016:Q2) is expected to be much more modest than it would otherwise have been. Had the credit spread reverted to its normal level at its typical pace from February on, it would likely have subtracted another half a percentage point from GDP growth for the rest of 2016, according to the model (see the blue dashed line).

The right panel of the chart above also shows that the tightening in financial condition is not solely responsible for the recent slowdown in GDP growth. Indeed, as indicated by the red line, other shocks subtracted almost 1.5 percentage points from output growth in 2016:Q1. (These shocks reflect various temporary factors, whose effects vanish after 2016:Q1.)

Why did GDP growth not fall by more, then, with such a powerful combination of adverse shocks? According to the model, the answer lies in large part with monetary policy. Recall that as of 2015:Q2, the federal funds rate was expected to rise. For instance, in the March and June 2015 Summary of Economic Projections, the median “dot” for the federal funds rate target was between 0.5 percent and 0.75 percent for the end of 2015. The FRBNY DSGE model was projecting a similar increase, as indicated in the chart below. Both the June 1 and the July 1, 2015, Blue Chip Financial Forecasts projected the policy rate to be 0.5 percent on average in 2015:Q4. However, the FOMC decided to delay liftoff of the federal funds rate. In September 2015, it maintained the target range for the federal funds rate unchanged, citing that “recent global economic and financial developments may restrain economic activity somewhat and are likely to put further downward pressure on inflation in the near term.” The federal funds rate has remained considerably lower than had been forecast in the spring of 2015.

Federal Funds Rate

The model suggests that by maintaining the federal funds rate lower, the FOMC managed to substantially offset the effect of tightening financial conditions on the economy. As financial markets revised downward their expectations of interest rate renormalization, the rate at which firms and households could borrow remained low in spite of the increase in spreads. The gold line in the “Shock Decomposition” panel above suggests that the lower federal funds rate path managed to boost GDP growth by more than 1 percentage point for several quarters, essentially offsetting the negative effect of the tightening in financial conditions. In addition, FOMC communication early in 2016 was likely an important factor in the renormalization of financial conditions, although this is not well captured by the model.

In conclusion, the tightening in financial conditions reflected in the rapid rise in credit spreads from 2015:Q3 to 2016:Q1 caused a significant slowdown in growth, according to the FRBNY DSGE model. By delaying the federal funds rate liftoff, the FOMC managed to offset part of these adverse shocks. It is important to remember, however, that our analysis relies on a model that is necessarily a stylized representation of reality. As such, model implications need to be taken with caution.

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.



Del Negro MarcoMarco Del Negro is an assistant vice president in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Giannoni MarcMarc Giannoni is an assistant vice president in the Group.

Smith_micahMicah Smith is a senior research analyst in the Group.

How to cite this blog post:

Marco Del Negro, Marc Giannoni, and Micah Smith, “The Macro Effects of the Recent Swing in Financial Conditions,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics (blog), May 25, 2016, http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2016/05/the-macro-effects-of-the-recent-swing-in-financial-conditions.html.

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

James: Thank you for your comment. You are absolutely right that we should show the uncertainty surrounding our estimates. That said, on the basis of the width of the credible intervals around impulse responses to spread shocks, and given the precision with which these shocks are estimated, we are reasonably confident that the effects of spread shocks shown in the shock decomposition chart (blue line) are significantly different from zero.

Enjoyed this analysis. One quick question, what was the impact of the hike in Dec? If the FOMC had not raised rates, how much more benefit from Policy Shocks (gold line, right panel) could have occurred? Would that have caused a smaller “miss” in the actual vs forecast in the left panel?

This is a nice analysis, but it would be a lot more credible if you reported confidence intervals around the forecasts and shock decompositions.

The comments to this entry are closed.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives