Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

March 19, 2012

Failure Is No Longer a (Free) Option for Agency Debt and Mortgage‑Backed Securities

Michael J. Fleming

A recommended charge on settlement fails for agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities (MBS) took effect on February 1, 2012. This follows the successful introduction of a charge on settlement fails for U.S. Treasury securities in 2009. With a fails charge, a seller of securities that doesn’t deliver on time must pay a charge to the buyer. The practice is meant to ensure that sellers have adequate incentive to deliver securities without undue delay and thereby reduce the level of settlement fails. In this post, I discuss how and why the fails charge was implemented.



Settlement Fails before the Fails Charge
Historically, market practice was to allow a failing seller to deliver after the original contracted settlement date at an unchanged invoice price. As the buyer didn’t pay the seller until delivery of the securities, the seller lost (and the buyer gained) the time value of the transaction proceeds over the fail interval. The prospect of losing the time value of money on the transaction proceeds provided incentive for the seller to deliver on the settlement date or as soon as possible thereafter.

    While the historical practice worked well in normal interest rate environments, it proved inadequate in low-rate environments. As explained in this white paper, there’s limited incentive to borrow securities to avoid failing in a low-rate environment because the cost of failing, as measured by the time value of money, is commensurately low. As shown in the chart below, agency MBS settlement fails surged in 2003-04 as the target fed funds rate was lowered to 1 percent. They again increased sharply after the rate was lowered to its current 0-25 basis point range in December 2008.

Agency-MBS-fails-increase-in-low-rate-environment

Costs of Fails
Settlement fails matter to both the counterparties of a trade and to market participants more generally. To the counterparties, fails can increase operational costs and counterparty credit risk, absorb scarce capital through regulatory charges, and hurt customer relations. More generally, persistent settlement fails at a high level can cause participants to withdraw from the market, adversely affecting market liquidity and stability. The Treasury Market Practices Group (TMPG) cited these costs in its announcement proposing fails charge recommendations.[1]

Fails Charge Recommendations
The fails charge recommendations are modeled on the TMPG’s earlier fails charge recommendation for Treasury securities, but reflect the particular characteristics of the agency debt and agency MBS markets. As with the Treasury fails charge, the agency debt and agency MBS fails charges only kick in when short-term interest rates are low, so as to provide a solution narrowly tailored to the problem. As explained in this TMPG announcement, the charge for agency debt securities, like that for Treasury securities, ranges between 0 and 3 percent (it’s 3 percent per year in the current environment, but would be zero if the fed funds rate was at or above 3 percent). The charge for agency MBS ranges between 0 and 2 percent, as the TMPG explains in this announcement. The charge for agency debt securities, like that for Treasury securities, applies to fails outstanding a day or more, whereas the agency MBS charge only applies to fails outstanding three days or more. In both cases, charges of small dollar amounts are waived to minimize operational costs.

Will the Fails Charge Be Effective?
Will the fails charge reduce settlement fails? There are several reasons to think so. First, the increased cost of failing resulting from the charge provides a greater incentive for market participants to avoid fails in low-rate environments. Second, evidence from the May 2009 adoption of a fails charge for Treasury securities suggests that the charge in that market has been successful at reducing fails, as shown in the chart below. Lastly, the TMPG has said that it will closely monitor fails under the new regime, and that it may raise the level of the charge if its initial recommendation proves inadequate at reducing fails.

Treasury-Fails-Decline-with-Introduction-of-Fails-Charge


[1] The TMPG is a group of market professionals, sponsored by the New York Fed, committed to supporting the efficiency of the Treasury, agency debt, and agency MBS markets.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author.

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

I agree with Michael Fleming’s analysis. Both the existence of the fail penalty and experience with a similar penalty for treasuries suggest that this rule will be successful at reducing MBS repo failures in a low rate environment. This should, in turn, improve market efficiency and stability. Failures generate negative network (knock-on) externalities. Thank you Michael.

The comments to this entry are closed.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives