Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

April 3, 2013

I Want My Money Now: The Highs and Lows of Payments in Real Time

Parinitha Sastry and David Skeie

Peel back the layers of complex financial institutions and instruments, and you’re left with individuals demanding to be paid, and to be paid quickly. Payments are the electricity that powers the entire financial system. The ability to securely send and receive timely payments is a prerequisite for commerce and the smooth functioning of financial markets. Despite the seemingly straightforward nature of the subject, a preliminary exploration of payments data offers insight into how institutions react to changing economic conditions. In this post, we aim to investigate recent volatility in the amount of payments, particularly during the recent financial crisis. We focus on estimating and extracting changing levels of payments required for interbank lending, which reflect banks’ varying needs for liquidity. We find that variables capturing macroeconomic conditions and financial market stress are additional large drivers of fluctuations in payments.


Depository institutions and government agencies make trillions of dollars in payments every day. The Fedwire® Funds Service is the Federal Reserve’s payments network over which billions of dollars can flow within seconds throughout the country. Just as payments are the electricity of the financial system, the Fedwire Funds Service is the circuitry. The service allows over 7,000 depository institutions and other participants to electronically transfer funds to each other on behalf of themselves and their customers, which include deposit account holders and other financial institutions. Additionally, the Fedwire Funds Service plays a versatile payments role for a variety of institutions other than depository institutions, including foreign exchange settlement groups, the U.S. Treasury, and other federal and international agencies (for more on the operation of the service, see this August 2012 post).

Between 2002 and 2008, the value (dollar volume) of payments grew steadily upward. However, as the chart below shows, this trend becomes more volatile after the onset of the financial crisis, the start of which we identify as BNP Paribas’ announcement to freeze three asset-backed-securities investment funds when the securities couldn’t be fairly valued.

Fedwire-Payments-Over-Time

Much of the dramatic fluctuations in Fedwire payments become more muted after one removes overnight loans made or intermediated by banks, which are a primary set of transactions that pass through the Fedwire Funds Service. Overnight loans are a key source of short-term funding for banks, particularly when they’re strapped for cash. We estimate such loans using a statistical algorithm originated by former Fed economist Craig Furfine that aims to match payments over the Fedwire Funds Service into corresponding pairs. By way of disclaimer, we note that, historically, algorithms based on the work of Furfine have been used as a method of identifying overnight or term federal funds transactions. The Research Group of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York has recently concluded that the output of its algorithm based on the work of Furfine may not be a reliable method of identifying federal funds transactions. (It should be noted that for its calculation of the effective federal funds rate, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York relies on different sources of data, not on the algorithm output.) The output of the algorithm may include transactions that are not fed funds trades and may discard transactions that are fed funds trades. Some evidence suggests that these types of errors in identifying fed funds trades by some banks may be large. This post therefore refers to the transactions that are identified using the Research Group’s algorithm as overnight or term loans made or intermediated by banks. Use of the term “overnight or term loans made or intermediated by banks” in this post to describe the output of the Research Group’s algorithm is not intended to be and should not be understood to be a substitute for or to refer to federal funds transactions.

     As one can glean from the chart below, even after we remove these overnight loan transactions from the data set, we still observe a fluctuating series, with a large run-up in payments leading to the financial crisis and extreme fluctuations in Fedwire payments levels thereafter.

Components-of-Payment-Values-Over-Time

A simple linear regression on traditional macroeconomic and financial variables illuminates what drives the fluctuation in payments activity. We include in the regression (see table below) the three-month spread between the London interbank offered rate (Libor) and the overnight indexed swap (OIS) rate, a measure of financial market illiquidity and banking financial distress, as well as New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) volume as a measure of financial market activity. GDP is included to account for general movements in the economy at large, and a last-day-of-quarter dummy captures any end-of-quarter “window dressing” effects. Finally, period dummies are included to demarcate various phases of the financial crisis. The events we use to split up our sample are, in order, the BNP Paribas announcement to freeze three investment funds, the buyout of Bear Stearns, the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers, and the introduction by the Federal Reserve of interest payments on excess reserves (IOER) as excess reserves broadly increased.

Table

All of these variables are positive and highly significant. The positive coefficient for GDP likely reflects that demand for commercial payments increases as the economy grows, holding the other regression variables constant. As expected, overall financial market activity, represented by the volume of trades on the NYSE, is highly correlated with payments transfers.

Interestingly, the positive coefficient for the Libor-OIS spread implies that increasingly illiquid financial market conditions are highly correlated with payments values. One possible explanation for this finding could be that during times of bank funding stress, banks and other market participants may be more forceful in demanding immediate payment to reduce counterparty exposures, rather than waiting to receive offsets later, resulting in larger payments values on average.

Furthermore, the size and sign of the coefficients for our period dummies are consistent with the striking up-and-down pattern of the series. The constant represents the average value of Fedwire payments before the start of the crisis (pre-BNP). Compared with precrisis, the post-BNP periods have larger average values of aggregate payments. In particular, the alternating magnitudes of the coefficients for the period dummies in the post-BNP periods capture the fluctuations of payments volumes, as the coefficient for the Bear-to-Lehman period is smaller than that for the BNP-to-Bear period, and the coefficient for the post-IOER period is smaller than that for the Lehman-to-IOER period. In summary, our R2 value indicates that our model captures 50.9 percent of the variation in payments.

In the stacked-area chart below, we plot each variable’s contribution to the overall Fedwire series, so that the cumulative sum of the stacks yields the original Fedwire values. We multiply each regression coefficient by the values of its corresponding independent variable and add overnight loans. We observe that the bottom series, which includes the regression residual as well as the effect of the period dummies and the change in GDP, is indeed flatter than the raw Fedwire series, especially during the financial crisis; this illustrates that a large amount of variation in Fedwire payments values is accounted for by the other variables in the regression. Lastly, the monthly average of the last-day-of-quarter effects can be seen at the top of the chart.

Determinants-of-Fedwire-Payments

Our results capture how a growing economy requires increasing levels of payments, and how in times of turmoil payments levels respond to growing demands for immediacy. Further exploration into these findings will shed light on how these variables relate.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.


Sastry_parinitha
Parinitha Sastry is a senior research analyst in the New York Fed’s Research and Statistics Group.

Skeie_david
David Skeie is a senior economist in the Research and Statistics Group.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives