Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

July 15, 2015

A Discussion of Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty‑First Century: Does More Capital Increase Inequality?

LSE_2015-PikettyRG1_pinkoviskiy_art_photo-450

Second in a two-part series

My aim in the second post of this series on Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century is to talk about the economist’s research accomplishment in reconstructing capital-output ratios for developed countries from the Industrial Revolution to the present and using them to explain why wealth inequality will rise in developed countries. I will then provide a critical discussion of his interpretation of the history of capital in the developed world. Finally, I’ll end by discussing Piketty’s main policy proposal: the global tax on capital.

Capital and Output in Developed Economies

Piketty argues that if savings rates and growth rates do not change over the long run, the ratio of the capital stock to output should also tend to a constant long-run value. The core empirical observation in Capital is that the capital stock in developed economies is returning to its old long-run level of about six or seven times the size of annual output, after having been depressed for half a century at a level of three to four times annual output. We can see the evolution of the capital stock in several major European countries in the chart below. For most of the Industrial Revolution, these countries’ capital stock was between 600 percent and 700 percent of their GDP. During World Wars I and II, as well as during the Great Depression, large amounts of private capital were physically destroyed, depreciated, or lost value through inflation and regulation. Subsequently, the capital-output ratio remained low because of temporary rapid postwar growth of output, but also because of inflation and heavy regulation and taxation of capital, which decreased the rate of return to capital. However, its natural trend was to recover to its old steady state, which it did by the beginning of the twenty-first century, accompanied by developed-country governments lowering capital taxes and regulation, and getting inflation under control.

Figure I-2 Capital in the Twenty-First Century
Note: We publish the chart verbatim from the original in Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2014).

Piketty further argues that this rise in the capital-output ratio translated into a rise in the share of output earned by capital. If capital and labor can be easily substituted for each other in the long run (such as through the mechanization of routine tasks), then the interest rate should not react substantially to changes in the capital-output ratio. Capital shares should rise together with capital-output ratios. Indeed, over this period, capital shares in developed economies (with Britain as an example) have exhibited a similar U-shaped pattern to the capital-output ratio, albeit less pronounced.

Figure 6-1 The Dynamics of the Capital-Income Ratio
Note: We publish the chart verbatim from the original in Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2014).

Finally, Piketty presents evidence to show that wealth inequality in developed countries (again, with Britain as an example) has been moving together with the share of output going to capital.

LSE_2015-PikettyCapital2_pinkoviskiy_art-fig10-3-the-structure-of-inequality

Note: We publish the chart verbatim from the original in Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2014).

Piketty calls his book “primarily. . . about the history of the distribution of income and wealth” and writes this history masterfully. He draws his statistics from tax, estate, and probate records, as well as the national accounts and wealth surveys of the largest developed economies of the industrial period, and accomplishes a tour de force in synthesizing different data sources to generate his series for these countries’ capital stocks. It is telling that when journalists from the Financial Times found fault with some of Piketty’s choices on exactly how to construct some of the data series, they found that their preferred methods of construction yielded very similar results.

Does capital deepening lead to inequality?

While Piketty is correct that the capital-output ratio will likely rise in the long run, and that capital and labor are highly substitutable, it is unlikely that the rise in the capital-output ratio should increase the share of output that ends up as capitalists’ net income. It is well-known that capital depreciates: machines break and buildings need repair and refurbishment after they have been used. Therefore, what the capitalist cares about is not just how much revenue she gets from operating a machine, but how much of that revenue is left over after restoring the machine to its initial condition (her net profit). Hence, while Piketty is right that the gross share of output going to capital is likely to continue increasing, the share of output that is the net profit of capital may well decrease. In fact, a recent Brookings Paper on Economic Activity argues that the increases in the capital-output ratio that Piketty envisions would even reduce the share of output that owners of capital would have left for consumption and investment after depreciated capital is replaced.

It is worth noting that Piketty’s story of rising capital income inequality is a prognosis for the future, rather than an explanation of current increases in income inequality. In particular, it has relatively little to do with the sharp rise in inequality that the United States has experienced in the last forty years, which mostly has resulted from an increase in labor income inequality (the growth of the highest salaries), rather than from an increase in the inequality of income coming from capital.

Piketty’s Policy Proposal

Piketty is dismayed by the prospect of a return to nineteenth-century wealth inequality. Among the problems he finds with it are:

  • A lack of meritocracy. If the private, after-tax rate of return to capital r exceeds the growth rate g for a sustained period of time, inheritances will grow faster than labor market incomes, and obtaining a large inheritance (or marrying into one) will be a surer road to wealth than working hard at a profession.
  • Misallocation of capital, with wealthy people increasingly being likely to be economically inactive, elderly rentiers. If financial markets are imperfect—which they are, especially for younger, poorer people with few assets to use as collateral—new entrepreneurs may find it difficult to obtain funding for profitable ideas.
  • Inequality in political voice, with the very wealthy dominating the political agenda.

To try to maintain the low level of inequality of the mid-twentieth century, Piketty proposes a global tax on capital. The aim of this tax would be to lower the rate of return on capital r that private individuals would receive. It would replicate the situation of fifty or so years ago, when after-tax r was lower than g, and owners of capital had a hard time maintaining and passing down their fortunes. Piketty argues that such a tax would have to be global to avoid individual countries not taxing so that they can attract investment from countries that do, which has been the main mechanism for the decline in capital taxation in the developed world.

What should we do?

Piketty identifies valid reasons to be worried about inequality. However, in contrast to his extremely well-researched history of inequality, he does not present a systematic view of the empirical evidence that can help society balance the benefits of equality with the costs of decreasing inequality through taxation. It is likely that meritocratic societies grow faster in the long run, but we do not know by how much. Neither do we know how substantial the distortions are from capital misallocation. It is likewise difficult to quantify the importance of money in politics. Piketty’s preferred policy—taxation of capital—also has costs because, like any other tax, it will discourage the taxed activity—saving, investment, the accumulation of capital, and eventually economic growth, at least in the long run. What the reader of Capital does not get is a quantitative assessment of which costs matter more. More targeted measures, such as improving financial and political institutions, could also deal with the costs of inequality in a more surgical way than a tax on capital, as highlighted by Acemoglu and Robinson (2015).

One policy prescription that Capital implies is that supporting economic growth should help keep inequality low. Higher rates of growth (if r remains steady) decrease the gap r – g and lower the steady-state capital-output ratio. So, an additional argument for policies aimed at improving the overall efficiency of the economy—such as reforming education, streamlining regulations, or investing in public goods—is that they decrease the influence of established fortunes, to the extent that such influence is bad.

Piketty has revitalized study of the distribution of income and restarted a conversation about the role of inequality in society. He has also identified potentially important mechanisms through which wealth inequality may rise in the future. However, it appears likely that Piketty overestimates by how much inequality may continue to increase, and how much of a problem it may be to society. In addition, his policy prescriptions do not marshal the same weight of evidence as does his positive analysis.

Related Post

A Discussion of Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century: By How Much Is r Greater than g?

Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author.


  Pinkovskiy_maxim
Maxim L. Pinkovskiy is an economist in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives