Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

November 4, 2019

Since the Financial Crisis, Aggregate Payments Have Co‑moved with Aggregate Reserves. Why?

Since the Financial Crisis, Aggregate Payments Have Co-moved with Aggregate Reserves. Why?

Fedwire Funds, a key payment system in the United States, is used by banks to wire money to one another throughout the day. Historically, the total value of payments sent over Fedwire has been roughly proportional to economic activity. Since the financial crisis, however, we have instead observed a strong co-movement between total payments and the level of aggregate reserves. This co-movement suggests that a fraction of every dollar of reserves created recirculates on a daily basis. In this post, we investigate why total payments, a flow variable driven by real and financial activity, would co-move with total reserves, a stock variable controlled by the Federal Reserve.


The chart below illustrates the relationship between nominal GDP, total reserve balances at the Fed, and the value of payments sent over Fedwire. Before the 2008 crisis, the aggregate value of Fedwire payments grew roughly in line with GDP, consistent with the intuitive notion that total payments co-move with overall economic activity. But since the crisis, as reserves have significantly increased as a result of the Federal Reserve’s large-scale asset purchases, total payments have been co-moving with the total stock of reserves. This co-movement suggests a type of activity involving large payments that is proportional to the level of reserves. To understand this activity, we study the parties involved in the payments that underlie the co-movement.


Since the Financial Crisis, Aggregate Payments Have Co-moved with Aggregate Reserves. Why?

What Drives the Co-movement between Payments and Reserves?

The expansion of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet through crisis intervention and post-crisis asset purchases coincides with the introduction of interest on reserves (IOR) in 2008. All depository institutions with accounts at the Federal Reserve receive interest on their account holdings. However, since there are many financial market participants who do not have access to interest on reserves, several money market interest rates, including the federal funds rate, have remained below IOR for most of the period since 2008. This provides an opportunity for banks to borrow from other financial market participants at a rate below IOR, hold the funds as reserves, and earn the interest rate difference. Each of these loans leads to two payments on Fedwire—the transfer of the initial loan amount to the bank and, later, the repayment from the bank. Further, the aggregate scope of this “IOR arbitrage” activity (which is not limited to the fed funds market) is proportional to the aggregate level of reserves. IOR arbitrage activity is therefore a prime candidate for driving the co-movement between payments and reserves.

The banks in the best position to participate in IOR arbitrage activity are U.S. branches of foreign banks. These banks are able to hold reserves earning interest and to participate in the Fedwire payment system. However, in contrast to U.S. banks and U.S. subsidiaries of foreign banks, branches of foreign banks often face less demanding Basel III leverage ratios since these foreign banks are not subject to the stricter U.S. implementation of Basel III leverage regulation. In addition, these branches do not have insured deposits and therefore do not pay Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) fees that are based on total debt. Thus, branches of foreign banks are more willing than domestic institutions to borrow and hold the funds as excess reserves, thereby increasing their leverage and the size of their balance sheet. This dynamic has been well documented in studies showing that U.S. branches of foreign banks are the largest participants in IOR arbitrage markets.

The next chart shows that the co-movement between payments and reserves is most striking in payments involving a foreign branch as the receiver or sender, as would be the case for an IOR arbitrage loan or repayment, respectively. This result is consistent with the idea that IOR arbitrage activity may be driving the co-movement between payments and reserves.


Since the Financial Crisis, Aggregate Payments Have Co-moved with Aggregate Reserves. Why?

Who Is Sending the Payments?

If foreign branches are one of the main parties in borrowing activity driving the co-movement, what entities compose the other parties? Previous studies have found that, in the post-2008 period, the vast majority of lenders in the federal funds market have been government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs), such as Federal Home Loan Banks. GSEs have accounts at the Federal Reserve but are not eligible for IOR and therefore have a strong incentive to lend their excess funds to someone else if they can earn a positive interest rate. However, the next chart shows that reserves co-move with payments sent by non-GSE banks, rather than with payments sent by GSEs. Moreover, there is no immediate link between the reserves GSEs have available to lend and the aggregate level of reserves determined by the Federal Reserve, mainly through asset purchases. We therefore have to look outside of the federal funds market, to nonbanks, as the potential lenders in the IOR arbitrage loans.


Since the Financial Crisis, Aggregate Payments Have Co-moved with Aggregate Reserves. Why?

The increase in aggregate reserves since 2008 stems from the Federal Reserve’s purchases of Treasury securities and mortgage-backed securities (MBS) from both banks and nonbanks. Previous posts explain this mechanism for Treasuries and MBS: in a purchase from a bank, the Fed credits the bank’s Fed account with reserves, while in the case of a purchase from a nonbank, such as a money market fund, the Fed credits the Fed account of the nonbank’s custodian bank. Carpenter et al. (2014) show that most of the securities purchased after the crisis came from nonbanks. In the first round of asset purchases from 2008 to 2010, the Fed purchased $300 billion in Treasury securities, of which an estimated 70 percent came from nonbanks. The Fed also purchased $1.25 trillion in MBS, of which more than 60 percent came from nonbanks. In the second round of purchases from 2010 to 2011, the Fed bought $600 billion in Treasury securities, with an estimated 70 percent again coming from nonbanks. From the point of view of a nonbank, these transactions exchange a Treasury or MBS security for a deposit at the nonbank’s custodian bank. This deposit, equivalent to a loan, likely pays low or no interest, incentivizing the nonbank to invest the funds elsewhere.

One alternative to the loan to its custodian bank is a loan to a foreign branch that would offer a higher interest rate because the foreign branch engages in IOR arbitrage. Such a loan requires a transfer of the funds from the custodian to the foreign branch. If this hypothesis holds true, we would expect to see a relationship between reserve balances and payments from custodian banks to foreign branches. The next chart, which splits payments to foreign branches by type of sending bank, confirms that the payments of the five largest custodian banks in the U.S. co-move with reserves.


Since the Financial Crisis, Aggregate Payments Have Co-moved with Aggregate Reserves. Why?

Summing Up

Underlying the striking co-movement between total payments and total reserves in the post-crisis period are payments from custodian banks to U.S. branches of foreign banks (and back). Combined with the evidence of Carpenter et al. (2014) that most of the large-scale asset purchases came from nonbanks, our result is consistent with nonbanks substituting their previous securities holdings in part with lending to foreign branches. Surprisingly, the payments required in these lending transactions are large enough to significantly affect aggregate payments in the economy.

Since the Federal Reserve began reducing the size of its balance sheet, the federal funds rate and other money market rates have risen closer to IOR and, in the recent past, surpassed IOR. Because this increase of other interest rates reduces or eliminates the potential for IOR arbitrage, we expect the co-movement between total payments and total reserves to weaken in the future.


Thomas EisenbachThomas Eisenbach is a senior economist in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Kyra Frye was a summer analyst in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

Helene HallHelene Hall is a senior research analyst in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

How to cite this post:

Thomas Eisenbach, Kyra Frye, and Helene Hall, “Since the Financial Crisis, Aggregate Payments Have Co-moved with Aggregate Reserves. Why?,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics, November 4, 2019, https://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2019/11/since-the-financial-crisis-aggregate-payments-have-co-moved-with-aggregate-reserves-why.html.


Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives