Liberty Street Economics

« | Main | »

October 7, 2019

Some Places Are Much More Unequal than Others

Some Places Are Much More Unequal than Others

Economic inequality in the United States is much more pronounced in some parts of the country than others. In this post, we examine the geography of wage inequality, drawing on our recent Economic Policy Review article. We find that the most unequal places tend to be large urban areas with strong economies where wage growth has been particularly strong for those at the top of the wage distribution. The least unequal places, on the other hand, tend to have relatively sluggish economies that deliver slower wage growth for high, middle, and lower wage earners alike. Many of the least unequal places are concentrated in the Rust Belt. These differences in the degree of wage inequality are tied to powerful economic forces arising from technological change and globalization, which have pushed up wages strongly for high-skilled workers in locations that have become the most unequal. Yet those same forces have kept wage growth compressed within a fairly narrow range for workers in places that are the least unequal.

Where Is Wage Inequality Greatest?

While there are many metrics for measuring wage inequality, they tend to be highly correlated and exhibit similar patterns. We focus on the ratio of the wages earned by a worker at the 90th percentile of the wage distribution to the wages earned by a worker at the 10th percentile, often referred to as the 90/10 ratio, which we show in the map below. The metropolitan areas in copper and yellow—with 90/10 ratios above 6—are the most unequal places in the country, while the metropolitan areas in blue—with 90/10 ratios below 5—are the least unequal places.

Many large urban areas, such as New York City, Washington, D.C., Chicago, Houston, Los Angeles, and the San Francisco Bay area, are among the most unequal places. Inequality is also relatively high in parts of the South, such as metro areas in Texas, Louisiana, and Alabama. By contrast, wage inequality is lowest in metropolitan areas in the Midwest and the Great Lakes region, often referred to as the “Rust Belt,” as well as in Washington State and some parts of Florida.


Some Places Are Much More Unequal than Others

What Makes Some Places More Unequal than Others?

These regional differences in wage inequality reflect the local effects of technological change and globalization on workers. These effects conform to one of two general patterns. In one set of places, technological change and globalization have led to a vibrant economy and strong demand for skilled labor. For example, San Francisco has seen a burgeoning tech sector in recent decades, resulting in strong demand and vigorous wage growth for highly skilled workers, especially those at the very top of the wage distribution. Likewise, skilled workers in the finance industry have been in strong demand in New York City, and their wages are particularly high. In places like these, wages for skilled workers toward the top of the wage distribution have increased significantly relative to those at the middle and bottom, resulting in relatively high levels of wage inequality.

In other places, technological change and globalization have led to weak economic conditions and lackluster wage growth across the board as these powerful economic forces have displaced many middle- and lower-skilled workers. This dynamic has played out in Detroit, for example, where the auto industry has eliminated thousands of jobs—cuts brought about both by automation and by auto plant closures, some of which have been tied to increased global competition. In addition to stagnant wages in the middle and lower portions of the wage distribution, demand for the most skilled workers has been weak in many of these places. This dynamic has resulted in sluggish wage growth for high-wage earners, which, when combined with slower wage growth among middle and lower skilled workers, has resulted in more compressed wage distributions than those seen in economies with stronger growth.

Other Factors at Work

While technological change and globalization have been the key drivers of these geographic patterns, there are two other important factors contributing to and reinforcing regional differences in wage inequality. First, agglomeration economies—or the benefits that arise when people and firms locate in large numbers near one another in cities—have enhanced the productivity and wages of skilled workers in large, dense metropolitan areas. While agglomeration economies have been shown to raise the productivity of all workers, recent research has found that these benefits tend to favor higher-skilled workers more than lesser-skilled workers. As a result, highly skilled workers in places where skill is concentrated tend to command even higher wages than they would earn elsewhere, amplifying wage inequality in those places. Second, migration within the United States has changed the mix of workers across places. Indeed, since the early 1980s, skilled workers have become much more geographically concentrated as those with college and graduate degrees have flocked to large cities while lesser-skilled workers have increasingly been priced out of such places—in no small part because of high and rising housing costs. This pattern of internal migration has reinforced the productivity benefits of agglomeration economies in many places.

Workers Affected Differently

These economic forces have affected workers very differently in various parts of the country. As a result, some places are now much more unequal than others. Indeed, as our analysis of the geography of wage inequality shows, relatively high regional wage inequality is often a consequence of strong but uneven economic growth, while a relatively low level of regional wage inequality is often the result of a weakening local economy. Thus, to the extent that policymakers wish to address inequality at the local/regional level, these findings are an important first step toward understanding the magnitude and sources of regional wage inequality.


Abel_jaisonJaison R. Abel is an assistant vice president in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Deitz_richardRichard Deitz is an assistant vice president in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

How to cite this post:

Jaison R. Abel and Richard Deitz, “Some Places Are Much More Unequal than Others,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Liberty Street Economics, October 7, 2019, https://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2019/10/some-places-are-much-more-unequal-than-others.html.

Additional heterogeneity posts on Liberty Street Economics.

Heterogeneity: A Multi-Part Research Series


Disclaimer

The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.

Comments

Feed You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.

Jeffrey: Many thanks for your comments on this post. In terms of the spatial unit of this analysis, we focus on metropolitan areas as they are a good approximation of local labor markets. So, yes, when we refer to Fairfield, CT, in this post it is the Fairfield County metro area, not the town.

I can only imagine you mean the Fairfield COUNTY metro area. Fairfield CT is a town of 60K people and hardly a metropolitan area, but you never use the word “county” in this publication.

The comments to this entry are closed.

About the Blog

Liberty Street Economics features insight and analysis from New York Fed economists working at the intersection of research and policy. Launched in 2011, the blog takes its name from the Bank’s headquarters at 33 Liberty Street in Manhattan’s Financial District.

The editors are Michael Fleming, Andrew Haughwout, Thomas Klitgaard, and Asani Sarkar, all economists in the Bank’s Research Group.

Liberty Street Economics does not publish new posts during the blackout periods surrounding Federal Open Market Committee meetings.

The views expressed are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect the position of the New York Fed or the Federal Reserve System.

Economic Research Tracker

Image of NYFED Economic Research Tracker Icon Liberty Street Economics is available on the iPhone® and iPad® and can be customized by economic research topic or economist.

Economic Inequality

image of inequality icons for the Economic Inequality: A Research Series

This ongoing Liberty Street Economics series analyzes disparities in economic and policy outcomes by race, gender, age, region, income, and other factors.

Most Read this Year

Comment Guidelines

 

We encourage your comments and queries on our posts and will publish them (below the post) subject to the following guidelines:

Please be brief: Comments are limited to 1,500 characters.

Please be aware: Comments submitted shortly before or during the FOMC blackout may not be published until after the blackout.

Please be relevant: Comments are moderated and will not appear until they have been reviewed to ensure that they are substantive and clearly related to the topic of the post.

Please be respectful: We reserve the right not to post any comment, and will not post comments that are abusive, harassing, obscene, or commercial in nature. No notice will be given regarding whether a submission will or will
not be posted.‎

Comments with links: Please do not include any links in your comment, even if you feel the links will contribute to the discussion. Comments with links will not be posted.

Send Us Feedback

Disclosure Policy

The LSE editors ask authors submitting a post to the blog to confirm that they have no conflicts of interest as defined by the American Economic Association in its Disclosure Policy. If an author has sources of financial support or other interests that could be perceived as influencing the research presented in the post, we disclose that fact in a statement prepared by the author and appended to the author information at the end of the post. If the author has no such interests to disclose, no statement is provided. Note, however, that we do indicate in all cases if a data vendor or other party has a right to review a post.

Archives